National Academies Press: OpenBook

Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy (2007)

Chapter: II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations

« Previous: I INTRODUCTION, The Emergence of the New Economy--Dale W. Jorgenson
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

II
FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

This page intentionally left blank.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

Findings and Recommendations

INTRODUCTION

The findings and recommendations found in this section reflect the Committee’s consensus based on its own deliberations as well as on the proceedings of five previous conferences that explored the operation of the new, information-based economy. The Committee’s aim is to understand the sources of productivity growth in this new economy, to measure more accurately the contributions of different components of growth, and to develop policies to encourage and increase that growth.

A.
THE NATURE OF THE NEW U.S. ECONOMY

Findings
  1. The New Economy refers to technological and structural changes in the U.S. economy as individuals capitalize on new technologies, new opportunities, and national investments in computing, information, and communications technologies. These structural changes have resulted in a long-term positive productivity shift of major significance.1

1

Dale W. Jorgenson and Kevin J. Stiroh, “Raising the Speed Limit: Economic Growth in the Information Age,” in National Research Council, Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy, Dale W. Jorgenson and Charles W. Wessner, eds., Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 2002, Appendix A.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
  1. Despite differences in methodology and data sources, a consensus has emerged among economists that the remarkable behavior of information technology (IT) prices provides the key to the surge in U.S. economic growth after 1995.

  2. The relentless decline in the prices of information technology equipment has steadily enhanced the role of IT investment across the economy.2 Productivity growth in IT-producing industries has risen in importance and a productivity revival is under way in the rest of the economy.

  3. The decline in IT prices refers to more than just a reduction in the price of a key economic input. The widespread use of IT, made possible by this price reduction, has changed and continues to change how individuals and businesses in the economy work, consume, communicate, and transact. New products and capabilities made possible by lower-cost computing and communications facilities are already restructuring the economy and accelerating the globalization of manufacturing and trade in services, with major positive implications for productivity growth.

  4. New information technologies have a broad and positive impact on U.S. productivity growth through industries that produce new information technologies and the many more that apply them. New IT applications are also contributing to enhanced workplace productivity as a wide variety of firms adapt to changes in information flows and take advantage of new organizational structures made possible by these innovations.3 These developments are changing the structure of firms, creating more innovative and more agile enterprises, with positive indirect and long-term implications for productivity growth.4

2

Kevin Stiroh notes that over the last decade, U.S. firms have invested over $2.4 trillion in IT assets, such as computer hardware, computer software, and telecommunications equipment and that these three assets accounted for more than 40 percent of private fixed investment in equipment and software in 2000. Kevin J. Stiroh, “Measuring Information Technology and Productivity in the New Economy,” World Economics 3(1):43-59, 2002.

3

These indirect effects are captured in a now substantial literature. For example, see Sandra E. Black and Lisa M. Lynch, “What’s Driving the New Economy?: The Benefits of Workplace Innovation,” Economic Journal, 114(493):F97-F116, 2004. See also Timothy Bresnahan, Erik Brynjolfsson and Lorin M. Hitt, “Information Technology, Workplace Organization and the Demand for Skilled Labor: Firm-level Evidence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1):339-376, 2002. For a discussion of how IT interacts with other aspects of firm structure, labor policies, and innovation such as human capital, improved organizational structure, and incentives, see Erik Brynjolfsson and Lorin M. Hitt, “Computing Productivity: Firm-Level Evidence,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(4):793-808, 2003.

4

See Amar Bhidé, “Venturesome Consumption, Innovation, and Globalization,” Paper prepared for a joint conference of CESIFO and the Center on Capitalism and Society on “Perspectives on the Performance of the Continent’s Economies,” Venice, July 21-22, 2006. Bhidé notes that an important part of innovation centers on the incentives facing firms and individuals in trying new products and reorganizing themselves to take advantage of new products.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
  1. Cheaper information technology has given greater importance to more productive forms of capital. The rising contribution of investments in information technology since 1995 has been a key contributor to the U.S. growth resurgence and has boosted growth by close to a percentage point.

    1. The contribution of investment in information technology accounts for more than half of this increase. Within information technology, computers have been the predominant impetus for faster growth. Communications equipment and software have also made important contributions to growth.

    2. Altogether, 31 industries (out of the 44 industry categories that make up the U.S. economy) contributed to the acceleration in economic growth after 1995. The four IT-producing industries discussed here are responsible for only 2.9 percent of the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) but a remarkable quarter of the U.S. growth resurgence.5 The 17 IT-using industries account for another quarter of the surge in growth and about the same proportion of the GDP, while the non-IT industries with 70 percent of value added are responsible for half the resurgence. The contribution of the IT-producing industries is far out of proportion to their relatively small size in relation to the economy as a whole. These industries have grown at double-digit rates throughout the period 1977-2000, but their growth jumps sharply after 1995, when the GDP share of these industries also increases.6

    3. The accelerated IT price decline also signals faster total factor productivity growth in IT-producing industries.7 The four IT-producing industries contributed more to the growth of total factor productivity during the period 1977-2000 than all other industries combined.8

5

Dale W. Jorgenson, Mun S. Ho, and Kevin J. Stiroh, Productivity, Volume 3: Information Technology and the American Growth Resurgence, Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 2005, p. 10.

6

Ibid., p. 11.

7

Total factor productivity is defined as output per unit of input, where input includes capital, labor, and intermediate inputs. There is some debate among economists about how easy it is to infer growth rates of total factor productivity growth from relative price declines. While Aizcorbe concludes that quality change was the dominant source of the increase in relative price declines in the mid-1990s, others might disagree. (See Ana Aizcorbe, “Why Are Semiconductor Prices Falling so Fast? Industry Estimates and Implications for Productivity Growth,” Economic Inquiry, forthcoming.) For example, Hobijn argues that declining margins cloud this linkage and Aizcorbe presents a model where increased competition leads to accelerated price declines. See Bart Hobijn, “Is Equipment Price Deflation a Statistical Artifact?” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report #139, November 2001. Also see Ana Aizcorbe, “Moore’s Law, Competition, and Intel’s Productivity in the Mid 1990s,” American Economic Review, 95:305-308, May 2005.

8

Dale W. Jorgenson, Mun S. Ho, and Kevin J. Stiroh, Productivity, Volume 3: Information Technology and the American Growth Resurgence, op. cit.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
  1. Gains in the U.S. terms of trade, especially for information technology products, may have contributed to the acceleration in U.S. productivity in the late 1990s.9

    1. Information technology is one of the most globally engaged sectors of the U.S. economy. Liberalization of information technology trade began in the 1980s, helping to decrease the cost of semiconductors and increase the availability of IT products and services.10 The International Technology Agreement of 1996 also eliminated all world tariffs on hundreds of IT products in four stages from early 1997 through 2000, helping to lower the prices of imported intermediate IT products.11

    2. While such trade effects are likely to explain only a small portion of the productivity speed-up, foreign trade practices do appear to matter for the measurement of productivity.

  1. Improved productivity associated with the introduction of advanced information and communications technologies appears to have raised the long-term growth trajectory of the U.S. economy. This gain appears to be robust, having survived the dot-com crash, the short recession of 2001, and the tragedy of 9/11. Since the end of the previous recession in 2001, productivity growth has been running at about two-tenths of a percentage point higher than in any recovery of the post-World War II period.12

  2. A structural change most associated with the New Economy today is the transformation of the Internet from a communication media to a platform for service delivery.13 This has contributed to the remarkable growth of the U.S. service

9

Robert C. Feenstra, Marshall B. Reinsdorf, and Michael Harper, “Terms of Trade Gains and U.S. Productivity Growth,” paper prepared for NBER-CRIW Conference, July 25, 2005.

10

For a detailed analysis of trade in semiconductors, see Kenneth Flamm, Mismanaged Trade, Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press, 1996. For a review of the impact of the 1986 semiconductor trade agreement on the revival of the U.S. semiconductor industry, see National Research Council, Securing the Future: Regional and National Programs to Support the Semiconductor Industry, Charles W. Wessner, ed., Washington, D.C.: The National Academies Press, 2003, p. 82. The report points out that the resurgence of the U.S. semiconductor industry was based in part on the success of the SEMATECH consortium, in part on the 1986 Semiconductor Trade Agreement, and in part on the repositioning of the U.S. industry away from DRAM chips and towards microprocessor design and production. The recovery of the U.S. industry was thus like a three-legged stool; it is unlikely that any one factor would have proved sufficient independently.

11

For an overview of the Information Technology Agreement and its implementation, access the World Trade Organization Web site at <http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/inftec_e/itaintro_e.htm>.

12

Dale W. Jorgenson, Mun S. Ho, and Kevin J. Stiroh, “Will the U.S. Productivity Resurgence Continue?” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Current Issues in Economics and Finance, 10(13), 2004.

13

This transformation is sometimes referred to as “Web 2.0.” For a description of this new version of the Web, see Tim O’Reilly, “What Is Web 2.0—Design Patterns and Business Models for the Next Generation of Software” September 30, 2005. Accessed at <http://www.oreillynet.com/pub/a/oreilly/tim/news/2005/09/30/what-is-web-20.html>.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

economy, as companies like Google and eBay increasingly exploit information services in new ways. As new business models, enabled by the Web, continue to emerge, they will contribute to sustaining the productivity growth of U.S. economy.

Recommendations
  1. Given the benefits of rapid technical innovation, the measurement issues associated with this change should be addressed on a systematic basis by the responsible agencies of the federal government in a coordinated fashion.

    1. Swiftly falling IT prices provide powerful economic incentives for the diffusion of information technology. Given that the rate of the IT price decline is a key component of the cost of capital, it is essential to develop constant quality indexes, such as those for computers, for use in the U.S. National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA).

    2. Substantial resources to develop price indexes and related analyses are needed to understand the sources of productivity growth in the economy and to develop the policies to sustain it.

  1. The growing synergies and new economic opportunities of the New Economy need to be understood better if they are to be sustained through appropriate policies. The rapid pace of these changes means that they require regular and systematic monitoring in order to bring significant changes to the attention of policy makers.

    1. The rapid business and workplace transformations made possible by information technology are not only a product of globalization but also a factor that is advancing globalization.14 For the United States, success in this new global paradigm requires technological leadership as well as strategic use of information technology.

    2. To remain a leader in information and communications technologies, the United States must foster and attract the best human resources. Both the federal and state governments must also adequately support research funding, and maintain a superior business environment and encourage the public-private partnerships that foster innovation and the timely transition of research to the marketplace.15 It must also update regulations that inhibit wider access to and use of information networks.16

14

Catherine L. Mann, High-Technology and the Globalization of America, forthcoming.

15

National Research Council, Government-Industry Partnerships for the Development of New Technologies: Summary Report, Charles W. Wessner, ed., Washington, D.C.: The National Academies Press, 2003.

16

National Academy of Sciences, National Academy of Engineering, and Institute of Medicine, Rising Above the Gathering Storm: Energizing and Employing America for a Brighter Economic Future, Washington, D.C.: The National Academies Press, 2007 Forthcoming.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

B.
MOORE’S LAW AND THE NEW ECONOMY

Findings
  1. Faster and cheaper semiconductors are a key driver of the productivity gains associated with the recent growth of the U.S. economy.17

    1. Price-performance improvement in semiconductors has been a major source of price-performance improvement in information technology. Declines in cost for electronics functionality embedded in semiconductors are the linchpin of improvement in price-performance for computers and communications, which in turn has been a major factor in the increase in long-term growth performance.18

    2. A substantial acceleration in the pace of IT price decline occurred in 1995, triggered by a much sharper acceleration in the price decline of semiconductors—the key component of modern information technology.19 (See Figure 1.20) This acceleration can be traced to a shift in the product cycle from 3 years to 2 years as a result of intensifying competition in markets for semiconductor products.21

17

Dale W. Jorgenson, Mun S. Ho, and Kevin J. Stiroh, Productivity, Volume 3: Information Technology and the American Growth Resurgence, op. cit.

18

Jack E. Triplett, “High-Tech Productivity and Hedonic Price Indexes,” in Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Industry Productivity, Paris: Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1996; Kenneth Flamm, “Technological Advance and Costs: Computers vs. Communications,” in Changing the Rules: Technological Change, International Competition, and Regulation in Communications, Robert C. Crandall and Kenneth Flamm, eds., Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1989; Ana Aizcorbe, Kenneth Flamm, and Anjum Khurshid, “The Role of Semiconductor Inputs in IT Hardware Price Declines” in Hard to Measure Goods and Services: Essays in Honor of Zvi Griliches, E. Berndt, ed., Chicago, IL: National Bureau of Economic Research, forthcoming.

19

Using industry estimates on Intel’s operations to decompose a price index, Ana Aizcorbe finds that virtually all of the declines in a price index for Intel’s chips can be attributed to quality increases associated with product innovation, rather than declines in the cost per chip. She adds that consistent with the inflection point that Jorgenson noted in the overall price index for semiconductors, the Intel price index falls faster after 1995 than in the earlier period, but that the decomposition attributes virtually all of the inflection point to an acceleration in quality increases. These increases in quality push down constant quality costs. See Ana Aizcorbe, “Why Are Semiconductor Price Indexes Falling So Fast? Industry Estimates and Implications for Productivity Growth,” op. cit. See also Dale W. Jorgenson, “Information Technology and the U.S. Economy,” American Economic Review, 91(1), 2001.

20

The output price index referred to in Figure 1 is the GDP deflator, but differs from the typical Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) GDP deflator due to methodology. We impute a capital service flow for government and consumer durable capital and use Tornqvist aggregation to add components of GDP.

21

For an analysis of the break points in prices of microprocessors, see Ana Aizcorbe, Stephen D. Oliner, and Daniel E. Sichel, “Shifting Trends in Semiconductor Prices and the Pace of Technological Progress,” mimeo, Federal Reserve Board, April. Other analyses focus on an acceleration in the pace of technological innovation in semiconductor manufacturing as accelerating the decline in prices: see Kenneth Flamm, “Microelectronics Innovation: Understanding Moore’s Law and Semiconductor

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

FIGURE 1 Relative prices of computers and semiconductors, 1959-2004.

NOTE: All price indexes are divided by the output price index.

  1. Although the decline in semiconductor prices has been projected to continue for at least another decade, the magnitude of recent acceleration may be temporary.

  1. Moore’s Law has played a significant role in the expectations and development of the semiconductor industry. While by no means dictating an actual law, Gordon Moore correctly foresaw in 1965 the rapid doubling of the feature density of a chip, now interpreted as approximately every 18 months.22

    1. While not pretending to be deterministic, Moore’s formulation has endured in part by setting expectations among participants in the semiconductor industry of the pace of innovation and the introduction of

Price Trends,” International Journal of Technology, Policy, and Management, 3(2), 2003; Kenneth Flamm, “The New Economy in Historical Perspective: Evolution of Digital Technology,” in New Economy Handbook, Derek C. Jones, ed., Academic Press, 2003; and Kenneth Flamm, “Moore’s Law and the Economics of Semiconductor Price Trends,” in Dale W. Jorgenson and Charles W. Wessner, eds., Productivity and Cyclicality in Semiconductors: Trends, Implications, and Questions, Washington, D.C.: The National Academies Press, 2004.

22

Observing that the number of transistors per square inch on integrated circuits had doubled every year since the integrated circuit was invented, Gordon Moore predicted in 1965 that this trend would continue for the near future. (See Gordon E. Moore, “Cramming More Components onto Integrated Circuits,” Electronics, 38(8), April 19, 1965.) The current definition of Moore’s Law, which has been acknowledged by Dr. Moore, holds that the data density of a chip will double approximately every 18 months. Many experts expect Moore’s Law to hold for another 15 years.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

new products to market.23 Each firm believes that its competitors will release the next model in an 18-month timeframe, leading each to set the pace of its own work on this basis—in effect making Moore’s Law a self-fulfilling prophecy.24 Currently, the industry expects to remain on the trajectory envisioned by Moore’s Law for another 10 to 15 years.25

  1. Making additional assumptions, an economic corollary to Moore’s Law is a rapid fall in the relative prices of semiconductors. With the acceleration in manufacturing innovation in the late 1990s came an increase in the rate of price decline—from roughly 15 percent annually in the early 1990s to 28 percent annually after 1995 until 2003. The increase in chip capacity and the concurrent fall in price—the “faster-cheaper” effect—have created powerful incentives for firms to substitute information technology for other forms of capital. These investments, when effectively integrated, have led to the productivity increases that are the hallmark of the phenomenon known as the New Economy.26

  1. The Semiconductor Industry Roadmap has helped to sustain Moore’s Law.

    1. The International Technology Roadmap for Semiconductors (ITRS) helps set the competitive pace of the semiconductor industry. By identifying common research challenges and reducing costs by identifying redundancies and technical “showstoppers,” the ITRS process helps the semiconductor industry commit to the investments necessary to stay on the growth trajectory of Moore’s Law.27

    2. In 1997, the ITRS reported the presence of a faster two-year semiconductor cycle beginning in 1995 that has helped to accelerate the pace of Moore’s Law. However, the 2003 edition of the ITRS has predicted that (given the difficulties encountered at the 90 nm technology node among other reasons) chipmakers will soon return to a 3-year cycle between technology nodes, significantly slowing the pace of semiconductor development.28

23

These expectations are reflected in the International Technology Roadmap for Semiconductors. Accessed at <http://public.itrs.net/>.

24

See Kenneth Flamm, “Moore’s Law and the Economics of Semiconductor Price Trends,” op. cit., 2004, and “Microelectronics Innovation: Understanding Moore’s Law and Semiconductor Price Trends,” op. cit., 2003. See also Ana Aizcorbe, “Moore’s Law, Competition, and Intel’s Productivity in the Mid-1990s,” BEA Working Paper WP2005-8, September 1, 2005.

25

See remarks by Robert Doering, “Physical Limits of Silicon CMOS Semiconductor Roadmap Predictions,” in National Research Council, Productivity and Cyclicality in Semiconductors: Trends, Implications, and Questions, op. cit.

26

Dale W. Jorgenson, “Information Technology and the U.S. Economy,” op. cit.

27

William Spencer, Linda Wilson, and Robert Doering, “The Semiconductor Technology Roadmap,” Future Fab International, 18, January 12, 2005.

28

Access the ITRS homepage at <http://public.itrs.net/>.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
  1. The semiconductor industry is characterized by high annual growth averaging around 15 percent per annum.29 This high growth rate is accompanied by considerable market volatility, reflected in significant cyclical swings in production.

    1. In large part, this volatility is because the semiconductor industry is highly capital-intensive, requiring significant capital expenditures for each fabrication facility and a very high intensity of R&D (sometimes up to 20 percent of revenue). This high level of investment underpins the high rate of innovation evident through increased performance, miniaturization, cost reduction, and short design cycles.30

    2. High sunk costs, steep learning curves, and rapid shifts in product cycles all contribute to a high level of industry cyclicality, which is one of the semiconductor industry’s distinguishing features.31

    3. A further aspect of the industry’s steep learning curves is the need for the research and at least some of the production facilities to be in close geographic proximity. This permits the many adjustments required to improve performance and yields and to adapt new equipment, production processes, and design features while adjusting to changing market conditions. The learning and synergies among university research, private laboratories, production and changing customer needs is a recognized feature of the semiconductor industry.32

    4. This does not mean that the benefits of proximity require all production to be located within a particular geographic area. This would imply a freezing of the allocation of global semiconductor production that would be neither possible nor desirable. On the other hand, having no on-shore production would inevitably erode the quality and robustness of research, design, equipment and materials production in the United States.

29

Despite industry cyclicality, the semiconductor industry achieved a 16.1 percent compound annual growth rate (CAGR) from 1975 to 2000. Growth during this period was driven by technological advances, the increasing pervasiveness of electronics in society, and the increasing capability of the semiconductors that powered new products and systems. This growth rate began to slow gradually starting in the mid-1980s, reaching about 15 percent in 1998. The severity of the 2001 downturn then prompted a reevaluation of the industry’s long-term growth rate. With semiconductor sales of $213 billion in 2004, the rate is now expected to be in the 8-10 percent range. The Semiconductor Industry Association forecast, released in June 2005, reflects this consensus and predicts a CAGR for the industry of 9.2 percent from 2004 to 2008. Accessed on the Semiconductor Industry Association Web site at <http://www.sia-online.org/iss_economy.cfm>.

30

European Semiconductor Industry Association, The European Semiconductor Industry: 2005 Competitiveness Report, op. cit.

31

Kenneth Flamm, “Factors Underpinning Cyclicality in the Semiconductor Industry,” in National Research Council, Productivity and Cyclicality in Semiconductors: Trends, Implications, and Questions, op. cit., pp. 61-64.

32

See, for example, European Semiconductor Industry Association, The European Semiconductor Industry: 2005 Competitiveness Report, op. cit.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
  1. The rapid rate of innovation means that products embedding semiconductor devices often have short life cycles. At the same time, the rate of price-performance improvement in the semiconductor industry is very rapid. Consequently, changes in the semiconductor market can occur very quickly, and established markets—and market leaders—can be swiftly displaced. In order to adjust constantly to this rapid pace of change, the semiconductor industry needs to be highly flexible and able to rapidly adopt new designs and new technologies. In this way, the rapid rate of innovation translates into high-capital requirements.33

  2. The high capital costs for fabrication facilities and the high R&D intensity make the industry sensitive to incentive schemes to attract and retain foreign and domestic semiconductor investment. Major competitors such as China, Japan, Korea, Malaysia, Singapore, Taiwan, and Europe have developed such incentive schemes. In the United States, these have been generated primarily at the state level (e.g., New York and Texas). It is important to recognize that lower wages and lower social costs are not determining factors in locational choices for semiconductor investments, whereas the existence of favorable incentive schemes, in particular tax regimes, is often the main source of competitive advantage.34

Recommendations
  1. Data and Modeling Challenges: Policies to foster continued improvement in the nation’s productivity and growth can be best developed with better data on prices and better models for prediction.

    1. Serious gaps in data prevent a full accounting of semiconductor-related prices.

    2. Although information technology is altering product markets and business organizations, a fully satisfactory model of the semiconductor industry remains to be developed. Such a model would derive the demand for semiconductors from investments in information technology in response to rapidly falling IT prices. An important objective is to determine the product cycle for successive generations of new semiconductors endogenously.

33

European Semiconductor Industry Association, The European Semiconductor Industry: 2005 Competitiveness Report, op. cit., p. 2.

34

European Semiconductor Industry Association, The European Semiconductor Industry: 2005 Competitiveness Report, op. cit., p. 4. This perspective is not new. As Laura Tyson famously observed, “the semiconductor industry has never been free of the invisible hand of government intervention.” Laura Tyson, Who’s Bashing Whom? Trade Conflict in High Technology Industries, Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics, 1992, p. 85.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
  1. Investments in Research and Training: Substantial investments in research and a well-trained workforce are needed if we as a nation are to continue to benefit from the growth and technological development offered by a vibrant, internationally competitive semiconductor industry.

    1. National Investments: National investments are necessary to provide the research and development facilities as well as a trained workforce well grounded in the disciplines—especially physics, chemistry, mathematics, computer science, and engineering—that underpin research and manufacturing in the semiconductor, computer component, and software industries.35 Such investments are also necessary for the nation to realize its substantial investments in nanotechnology, given its potential impact on computing, telecommunications, and semiconductor technology. National investments in these IT-related disciplines also continue to be important to capitalize on potential advances in biotechnology and related biomedical research. Scientific advances are increasingly multidisciplinary efforts and information technologies are often a key element in such advances.36

    2. Acquiring and Retaining Talent: Continual progress is also necessary in visa processing in order to attract and retain qualified foreign engineers and scientists. This includes increases in the number of H-1B visas; automatic visa extensions for international students who receive advanced degrees in science, technology, engineering, mathematics, and other fields of national need from U.S. institutions; as well as more permanent opportunities for science and engineering graduates to remain and contribute to the United States economy.37 Compensation packages

35

Previous analysis by the Board on Science, Technology, and Economic Policy (STEP) of trends in federal research funding found that “there has been a significant reduction in federal funding in certain of the physical science and engineering fields. These include fields whose earlier advances contributed to the surge in productivity and economic growth of the late 1990s and fields that underlie progress in energy production and conservation, pollution abatement, medical diagnosis and treatment, and other national priorities.” National Research Council, Trends in Federal Support of Research and Graduate Education, Stephen A. Merrill, ed., Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 2001.

36

This point was highlighted in the recent study of public-private partnerships led by Gordon Moore. See National Research Council, Capitalizing on New Needs and New Opportunities: Government-Industry Partnerships in Biotechnology and Information Technologies, Charles W. Wessner, ed., Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 2001.

37

The need for these actions is emphasized in the recent Congressionally mandated NAS/NAE/ IOM study, Rising Above the Gathering Storm: Energizing and Employing America for a Brighter Economic Future, op. cit. See, in particular, Actions C-4 through C-6, which call for continuing improvements in visa processing for international students, providing a one-year automatic visa extension to international students who receive doctorates or the equivalent in fields of national need, and the institution of a new skills-based, preferential immigration option that would significantly raise the chances of an applicant with doctoral-level education in science and engineering. Problems with H-1B visas remain acute, acting as an impediment to the retention and recruitment of high-value

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

for technology workers are also a factor for remaining competitive in attracting and retaining qualified scientists and engineers.38

  1. Partnering for Innovation: To sustain the technology trajectory envisaged by Moore’s Law requires advanced research to overcome emerging technological “brick walls” that threaten continued rapid advance. Substantial public funding and cooperative partnerships in semiconductor research are necessary if we are to continue to reap the benefits of remaining on the trajectory set out by Moore’s Law and for the United States to remain a robust global center for the research, development, and production of semiconductors.

    1. Sustained research and development is necessary for the semiconductor industry to overcome the limits of CMOS (complementary metal-oxide semiconductor) and develop post-CMOS technologies. Initiatives in this regard include fostering research and developments in nanotechnology and molecular electronics to replace and/or extend the life of advanced CMOS manufacturing technologies.39

    2. To maintain the innovative pace of the industry, with the attendant benefits for the U.S. economy, national investments in university research programs that explore and develop promising technologies are needed.

    3. Additional government investments in university research for programs that support and move promising technologies closer to commercialization are increasingly important to maintain the innovative pace of the semiconductor industry.40

    4. Public-private partnerships, involving cooperative research and development activities among industry, universities, and government laboratories can play an instrumental role in accelerating the development

human capital. See Wall Street Journal, “Lopsided Immigration Policy Could Induce Brain Drain,” June 22, 2005, p. A17.

38

National Research Council, Building a Workforce for the Information Economy, Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 2001, pp. 69-79.

39

The Committee on the Future of Supercomputing of the National Research Council similarly discusses the imperative to innovate the next generation of hardware for supercomputers. See National Research Council, Getting Up to Speed: The Future of Supercomputing, Susan L. Graham, Marc Snir, and Cynthia A. Patterson, eds., Washington, D.C.: The National Academies Press, 2005, Chapter 5.

40

Previous analysis by the STEP Board has underscored the importance of innovation partnerships such as The Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR) Program and the Advanced Technology Program in contributing to the development of new technologies. See National Research Council, The Advanced Technology Program: Assessing Outcomes, Charles W. Wessner, ed., Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 2001, p. 39. See also National Research Council, The Small Business Innovation Research Program: An Assessment of the Department of Defense Fast Track Initiative, Charles W. Wessner, ed., Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 2000.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

of new technologies and products.41 Industry experts believe that such partnerships provide the most promising strategy for sustaining Moore’s Law, given that the semiconductor industry’s ability to make smaller, faster, and cheaper integrated circuits is limited by the growing inability of individual firms to pay for the increasingly expensive research needed to achieve needed innovations.42

  1. In addition to pre-competitive research partnerships at the horizontal level (e.g., among semiconductor device manufacturers), vertical partnerships focused on integrated capacities along the supply chain are seen as increasingly important. The objective of the vertical partnerships is to ensure competitiveness across the development and production chain through synergistic relations among suppliers, manufacturers, and users of semiconductors.43

  2. Finally, it is important to recognize that innovation partnerships are increasingly international efforts, even as global markets for high-technology industries are increasingly competitive. Governments can serve as a facilitating agent to create the necessary credibility, commitment, and mutual trust among private firms in the formation of research consortia.44 International research consortia, such as SEMATECH and IMEC, demonstrate the benefits of such global cooperation by reducing the risks and costs associated with the development of new semiconductor technologies and the standards for their application.

  1. Wider adoption of road-mapping exercises by the computer and computer component industries (along the lines of the ITRS conducted by the semiconductor industry) can contribute to the industries’ ability to remain on the

41

Public-private partnerships involving cooperative research and development among industry, government, and universities can play an instrumental role in introducing key technologies to the market. For an overview of the conditions necessary for successful partnerships (including industry leadership, development and use of technology roadmaps, shared costs, and regular assessment) see National Research Council, Government-Industry Partnerships for the Development of New Technologies: Summary Report, op. cit., pp. 13-16.

42

A recent study by SEMI estimates that research required for continued scaling of integrated circuit devices, even without another wafer size increase, will cost some $16.2 billion by 2010. However, the equipment and materials suppliers, to whom the burden of research has shifted from chipmakers, are predicted to be able to afford an annual R&D budget of $10.4 billion, creating a $6 billion gap. SEMI, “Semiconductor Equipment and Materials: Funding the Future,” October 2005. Accessed at <http://content.semi.org/cms/groups/public/documents/homepervasive/p036611.pdf>.

See also Phil LoPiccolo, “The Six Billion Dollar Gap,” Solid State Technology, February 2006; and Robert Haavind, “Chipmaking’s Tough Economic Road Ahead,” Solid State Technology, March 2006.

43

European Semiconductor Industry Association, The European Semiconductor Industry: 2005 Competitiveness Report: Executive Summary, op. cit., p. 51.

44

For an assessment of the limits and challenges of international cooperation, see HWWA, IfW, and NRC, Conflict and Cooperation in National Competition for High-Technology Industry, Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 1996, pp. 54-61.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

growth path predicted by Moore’s Law with its contribution to the pace of innovation and growth.45

C.
MAINTAINING U.S. TECHNOLOGY LEADERSHIP IN SEMICONDUCTORS

Findings
  1. The semiconductor industry is a key driver for the future of advanced technologies in the United States. The distinctive features of this industry enable it to foster new opportunities for economic growth and support the global competitiveness of the U.S. products and services.

    1. As a technology enabler, the semiconductor permits the invention and use of a variety of valuable applications. Semiconductor-based information technology is also a general purpose technology, shared across a wide variety of uses. There is also the possibility of substantial network effects that can amplify the impact of advances in semiconductor technology.46 Indeed, semiconductor technologies already underpin a variety of products ranging from personal computers and mobile phones, to solutions and services, especially those provided through the Internet. Taken together, these features of information technology mean that advances in semiconductor technology can have substantial impacts on long-run economic growth.

    2. Through their pervasiveness, semiconductors have become keys to the competitiveness of the products of a broad range of new and “traditional” industries. For example, the automobile industry uses semiconductor-based information technologies to design and manufacture vehicles at lower cost. In addition, onboard microprocessors increasingly monitor fuel use and driver safety. By improving quality, lowering costs, creating new features, and increasing customization, microelectronics can help differentiate the products of traditional industries, helping make U.S. firms more globally competitive.47

45

An example is the roadmap exercise by the U.S. Display Consortium, which develops platform technologies for flat-panel displays. See <http://www.usdc.org/> for additional information.

46

On the role of general purpose technologies, see Timothy Bresnahan and Manuel Trajtenberg, “General Purpose Technologies: Engines of Growth?” Journal of Econometrics, 65(1):83-108, 1995. See also Elhanan Helpman, “General Purpose Technologies and Economic Growth: Introduction” in General Purpose Technologies and Economic Growth, Elhanan Helpman, ed., Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, pp. 1-13, 1998.

47

Similarly, for the role information technology is playing in reviving the competitiveness of the U.S. textile and apparel industry, see Lenda Jo Anderson et al., “Discovering the Process of Mass Customization: A Paradigm Shift for Competitive Manufacturing,” National Textile Center Annual Report, 1995.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
  1. The unique contributions of this industry are reflected in the policies and programs of almost all major global participants. The perceived importance of the industry to long-term economic growth and technological competency has resulted in an impressive array of policies, partnerships, subsidies, and investments that are intended to create, nurture, and retain the design, development, production, and refinement of semiconductors and related technologies.48

  1. Even as some production moves offshore, semiconductors remain important for the U.S. economy. The production and use of semiconductors are major contributors to the growth and dynamism of the U.S. economy. Access to and use of advanced semiconductors contribute to many national missions, not least national security.49

    1. Ever faster and cheaper semiconductors are recognized as key components in sustaining the productivity growth that the U.S. economy has experienced since 1995. The end of a two-decade slowdown in U.S. productivity growth that took hold in the 1970s and that coincided with a significant erosion of the country’s industrial power can be traced to a sudden speed-up in the rate of decline of semiconductor and computer prices.50

    2. The semiconductor industry is U.S. manufacturing’s star performer. In 2003, the industry saw worldwide sales of $166 billion, of which $80 billion were sales in the United States. (The U.S. semiconductor industry invests $14 billion in R&D, an amount that represents 17 percent of sales, with another 14 percent of sales [$10 billion] going towards the acquisition of capital equipment.) The industry provides about 226,000 jobs in the United States. While relatively small compared to the total U.S. workforce, these jobs are well-paid and have a disproportionately positive impact on the U.S. economy because of their remarkable productivity levels.51

    3. In light of the unique contributions of semiconductors to national growth and technical capacity in this information age, fostering a vigorous semiconductor industry in the United States is important for the nation’s

48

These multiple programs and incentives are documented by Tom Howell, “Competing Programs: Government Support for Microelectronics,” in National Research Council, Securing the Future: Regional and National Programs to Support the Semiconductor Industry, op. cit.

49

National Research Council, Productivity and Cyclicality in Semiconductors: Trends, Implications, and Questions, op. cit., 2004. See also National Research Council, Securing the Future: Regional and National Programs to Support the Semiconductor Industry, op. cit.

50

Dale W. Jorgenson, Mun S. Ho, and Kevin J. Stiroh, Productivity, Volume 3: Information Technology and the American Growth Resurgence, op. cit., 2005, Chapter 9.

51

Ibid. See also Semiconductor Industry Association, Industry Facts and Figures. Accessed at <http://www/sia-online.org/ind_facts.cfm> on December 13, 2005.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

long-term security and for its contributions to economic growth, productivity, and technological know-how.

  1. Structural Change: The structure of the semiconductor industry is changing, creating new vulnerabilities and challenges for U.S. leadership in this strategically important industry, while at the same time creating new opportunities.

    1. The semiconductor industry is characterized by a very high intensity of R&D and high levels of capital expenditures in semiconductor fabrication facilities. A modern fabrication facility is now in the $2 billion to $3 billion range, increasingly out of the reach of many manufacturers. Reflecting these high forced capital costs, the industry is highly sensitive to both the global research infrastructure and the incentives and disincentives that condition the financial returns on its investments.52

    2. The foundry model is now a significant component of the industry, having begun with Taiwanese government encouragement and investment in 1987.53 Foundry-based companies tend to spend a smaller percentage of their sales on R&D than do traditional integrated device manufacturers.54 Consequently, one potential impact of the growth in the foundry model maybe a fall-off in industry-sponsored research into process engineering, possibly posing long-term challenges to the pace of innovation in semiconductor manufacturing techniques. A shortfall in R&D directed to process improvements is unlikely to be made up by semiconductor design firms, which are smaller with less commitment to process technologies.

    3. At the same time, the foundry model permits easier entry and greater competition through the development and commercial application of

52

The European Semiconductor Industry Association (ESIA) estimates a 220 percent higher return on a facility in East Asia as a result of revenue incentives. ESIA, “The European Semiconductor Industry 2005 Competitiveness Report.” Accessed at <http://www.eeca.org/pdf/final_comp_report.pdf>. Locational competition continues to accelerate. In 2005, Germany attracted an AMD fab with very substantial incentives, including $700 million in loan guarantees, $500 million in grants and allowances, and $320 million in equity contributions. Recently, the State of New York provided about $1 billion in incentives for AMD to locate near Albany a new 300-mm wafer plant. It will make chips based on a 32-nm process and will take about $3.2 billion in capital to build. See PC Magazine, “AMD to Build Factory in New York,” June 26, 2006.

53

According to Wikipedia.org, in microelectronics, a foundry refers to a factory where devices such as integrated circuits are manufactured. The foundry model describes how businesses separate the design process from the manufacturing of these microdevices. For an account of the modern evolution of the foundry model, see Jon Sigurdson, “VSLI Revisited—Revival in Japan,” Working Paper No. 191, Tokyo: Institute of Innovation Research of Hitotsubashi University, p. 50, April 2004.

54

See comments by George Scalise on “The Foundry Phenomenon,” National Research Council, Productivity and Cyclicality in Semiconductors: Trends, Implications, and Questions, op. cit., p. 15.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

semiconductors with new cost and performance features that would otherwise not be available as rapidly or as attractively priced.55

  1. While globalization offers many benefits, if design, materials and equipment, and manufacturing capabilities move outside the United States, the United States risks losing the critical mass necessary for its leadership and autonomy in semiconductor technologies and equipment.56

  1. The movement of the semiconductor industry offshore is not uniquely the result of market forces. Semiconductors are produced and traded in a globally integrated market, and firms have significant interest in locating facilities in rapidly growing markets. Yet at the same time, national policies often condition international competition in semiconductors. Indeed, the policies of other nations and regions may well pose challenges to U.S. leadership in this sector.57

    1. Publicly supported, location-based competition for high-value-added, high-growth industries is one of the hallmarks of the global economy. Many governments in East Asia and Europe have adopted comprehensive and effective policies to attract, create, and retain semiconductor firms and related industries within their national economies.58 Governments adopt and finance these policies in order to secure national capacity and autonomy in this enabling technology, as well as the increased competitiveness and future government revenue associated with the semiconductor industry.59

    2. The United States has no current comparable national effort to retain and maintain the industry. SEMATECH, the government-industry partnership, was founded in 1987 at the height of the Japanese industry’s challenge to U.S. producers, and it proved effective in improving U.S. manufacturing capabilities.60 SEMATECH’s major international efforts

55

Jack Harding, “Current Trends and Implications: An Industry View,” in National Research Council, Software, Growth, and the Future of the U.S. Economy, Dale W. Jorgenson and Charles W. Wessner, eds., Washington, D.C.: The National Academies Press, 2006.

56

President’s Council of Advisors on Science and Technology, Sustaining the Nation’s Innovation Ecosystems, Washington, D.C.: Executive Office of the President, 2004, pp. 9 and 14.

57

National Research Council, Securing the Future: Regional and National Programs to Support the Semiconductor Industry, op. cit.

58

The European semiconductor industry affirms that national incentives are shaping international competition and calls for its governments and the EU technology programs to become more focused. See ESIA, “The European Semiconductor Industry 2005 Competitiveness Report,” op. cit.

59

For a review of national and regional programs, see Thomas Howell, “Competing Programs: Government Support for Microelectronics,” in National Research Council, Securing the Future: Regional and National Programs to Support the Semiconductor Industry, op. cit., pp. 254-284.

60

See National Research Council, Securing the Future: Regional and National Programs to Support the Semiconductor Industry, op. cit., pp. 41-43. See also Kenneth Flamm, “SEMATECH Revisited: Assessing Consortium Impacts on Semiconductor Industry R&D” in National Research Council,

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

began in 1996, and since 1998 SEMATECH has been a fully international research consortium. International SEMATECH receives no federal funding, though it has recently benefited from significant state support from Texas and more recently for its expansion in New York State.61 It now faces competition from IMEC, located in Flanders, a novel and effective research consortium supported with European Union, national government, and Flanders regional funds as well as contributions from private companies from all major regions.62

  1. Also fundamental to the development of the globally competitive semiconductor industry has been the opening of global markets that are relatively free from unfair trade practices. U.S.-led trade initiatives to open foreign semiconductor markets played a key role in establishing the conditions for international competition based on price and quality among multiple vendors.63

Recommendations
  1. To better address the technical challenges faced by the semiconductor industry and to better ensure the foundation for continued progress, more attention to the conditions and policies shaping locational decisions for this enabling industry is warranted.

  2. Renewed attention to encouraging and retaining a capable high-tech workforce is necessary.64 Most importantly, additional resources for university-

Securing the Future: Regional and National Programs to Support the Semiconductor Industry, op. cit., pp. 254-281.

61

Electronic News, “SEMATECH Adds 4 International Members,” June 21, 1999.

62

Jon Sirgurdson suggests that the more independent and flexible IMEC approach to employing new technical opportunities may reflect an advantage in international competition for research dollars and expertise. Sirgudson, “VSLI Revisited—Revival in Japan,” op. cit., pp. 48-49. IMEC receives some 35 million euros in “core support” from the Flanders regional funds.

63

In the mid-1980s, the United States, Japan, and Canada entered into agreements to eliminate tariffs, first on semiconductors, and then on parts of computers. Separately, the Japanese government and industry agreed to a market opening initiative and foreswore dumping in the United States and other markets. This had several effects: A Korean DRAM industry grew up under this regime, and the United States stayed in memory chip production, not only in DRAMs (Dynamic Random Access Memory, a type of memory used in most personal computers) but also in EPROMs (Erasable Programmable Read-Only Memory) and was able to enter the flash memory market. By the mid-1990s, the Japanese market had become completely open to foreign semiconductor makers. Vigorous price competition among a multiple vendor base ensured that prices and costs would decline sharply, enabling the growth of IT use and, with it, the Internet and globalization phenomena. For a detailed analysis of trade in semiconductors, see Kenneth Flamm, Mismanaged Trade, op. cit.

64

George Scalise, “Industry Perspective on Semiconductors,” in National Research Council, Securing the Future: Regional and National Programs to Support the Semiconductor Industry, op. cit., pp. 35-42. Google’s Wayne Rosing reiterated this need at the Committee’s workshop on “Software, Growth, and the Future of the U.S. Economy,” National Research Council, Software, Growth, and the

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

based research in related disciplines, such as physics, chemistry, materials sciences, and engineering, are required.65

  1. The federal and state governments should undertake measures that strengthen the attractiveness of the United States as a location for semiconductor research and production.

  2. Three-way partnerships among industry, academia, and government are needed to catalyze progress in the high-cost area of future process and design. These partnerships would:

    1. Sponsor more initiatives that encourage collaboration between universities and industry, especially through student training programs, in order to generate research interest in solutions to impending and current industry problems.

    2. Increase funding for successful current programs. For example, the Focus Center Research Program developed by the Semiconductor Research Corporation could usefully be augmented through increased direct government funding.66 These centers also represent opportunities for collaborative research with other federal outreach programs, such as those supported by the National Science Foundation.

    3. Create incentives for students. Augmented federal support for programs that encourage research in semiconductors would attract professors and graduate students. In addition, specific incentive programs could be established to attract and retain talented graduate students.67

  1. Active, rapid, and effective enforcement of international trade rules through the World Trade Organization (WTO) and other forums is needed to maintain

Future of the U.S. Economy, op. cit. See also remarks by Craig Barrett at a Semiconductor Industry Association event commemorating the 40th anniversary of Moore’s Law. Access news release at <http://www.sia-online.org/pre_release.cfm?ID=355>.

65

See the corresponding recommendation in National Research Council, Securing the Future: Regional and National Programs to Support the Semiconductor Industry, op. cit., pp. 88-89. See also more recent related recommendations concerning strengthening the nation’s traditional commitment to science and engineering in NAS/NAE/IOM, Rising Above the Gathering Storm: Energizing and Employing America for a Brighter Economic Future, op. cit.

66

The Microelectronics Advanced Research Corporation (MARCO) funds and operates university-based research centers in microelectronics technology. Its charter initiative, the Focus Center Research Program (FCRP), is designed to expand pre-competitive, cooperative, long-range applied microelectronics research at U.S. universities. Each Focus Center targets research in a particular area of expertise. In addition to strengthening ties between industry and the university research community, this model concentrates resources on the areas of microelectronics research that are critical in maintaining industry growth. More information can be accessed at <http://fcrp.src.org/Default.asp?bhcp=1>.

67

NAS/NAE/IOM, Rising Above the Gathering Storm: Energizing and Employing America for a Brighter Economic Future, op. cit.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

a competitive global market in semiconductors.68 The successful U.S. case against the Chinese value-added tax (VAT) rebate is a case in point.69

D.
DECONSTRUCTING THE COMPUTER

Findings
  1. Computers are widely recognized to be important components of economic growth and improved productivity associated with the New Economy, with the upward shift in economic growth coincident with declines in the prices of computers and related equipment.

    1. Indeed, it seems that the upward shift in the rate of economic growth in the mid-1990s coincided with a sudden, substantial, and rapid decline in the prices of computers (from 15 percent annually to about 28 percent annually after 1995, per the data graphed in Figure 270) accompanied by significant increases in computing power and function.

    2. This upward shift in growth also coincided with a shift in the rate of decline in price for memory and logic devices (from 40 percent annually to about 60 percent annually after 1995 per the data graphed in Figure 1).71

    3. Indeed, recent estimates suggest that between 40 and 60 percent of the decline in computer prices in the late 1990s, and perhaps 20 to 30 percent of the declines in communications equipment and consumer

68

WTO and other trade rules do not include a mandate for the enforcement of competition/antitrust policy; they only permit it. Enforcement of competition policy is necessary. Recently, Samsung Electronics of South Korea has agreed to plead guilty to charges of participating in an international conspiracy to fix prices in the DRAM market to the tune of $300 million, settling with the U.S. Department of Justice Antitrust Division. See Electronic News, “Samsung Faces $300M DoJ Fine for Price Fixing,” October 13, 2005.

69

In rapidly evolving industries, such as semiconductors, it is important that remedial trade actions to correct merchantalistic policies (e.g., through discriminatory taxation) be both prompt and effective. For example, the United States and China agreed in 2004 on a resolution to their dispute at the World Trade Organization (WTO) regarding China’s tax refund policy for integrated circuits. U.S. exports of integrated circuits to China were subject to a 17 percent value-added tax (VAT). However, China taxed domestic products significantly less, allowing firms producing integrated circuits in China to obtain a partial refund of the 17 percent VAT, lowering the effective VAT rate on domestic products to as low as 3 percent in some cases. These measures contributed to a very significant competitive advantage and a powerful incentive for inward investment, reflected in the surge in new production facilities in China.

70

The output price index referred to in Figure 2 is the GDP deflator, but differs from the typical BEA GDP deflator due to methodology. We impute a capital service flow for government and consumer durable capital and use Tornqvist aggregation to add components of GDP.

71

Dale W. Jorgenson and Kevin J. Stiroh, “Raising the Speed Limit: U.S. Economic Growth in the Information Age,” in National Research Council, Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy, op. cit.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

FIGURE 2 Relative prices of computers, communications equipment, and software, 1959-2004.

NOTE: All price indexes are divided by the output price index.

electronics, are directly attributable to declines in price for the semiconductor inputs used in these products.72

  1. The Moore’s Law phenomenon of “faster, cheaper, better” semiconductors is also present in the computer and computer component industries, accelerating the pace of technological innovation and lowering costs to consumers.

  2. Increased computing power enables a wider and more complex range of applications for both the specialist as well as the general user.

    1. The increased computing power in new and improved computer microprocessors is readily apparent to those “power users” who use their computers for scientific computing or modeling, games, and video and audio processing.

    2. It also of advantage to less demanding household computer users, improving the quality of their interface to their computers and enhancing their ability to handle high-resolution audio, video, and image files that are increasingly available over the Internet. Increased computing power also improves the speed and responsiveness of household computer

72

See Ana Aizcorbe, Kenneth Flamm, and Anjum Kurshid, “The Role of Semiconductor Inputs in IT Hardware Price Declines,” in Hard to Measure Goods and Services: Essays in Honor of Zvi Griliches, E. Berndt, ed., Chicago, IL: National Bureau of Economic Research, forthcoming.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

users in executing traditional applications (like word processing and spreadsheets), their ability to use features available in these traditional applications, and their ability to run multiple other applications (like anti-virus checkers, firewalls, multimedia plug-ins, messaging software, and search engines) concurrently with traditional applications without significantly degrading performance.

  1. Economists require accurate measures of the performance of computers and computer components in order to understand their contributions to economic growth.

    1. Developing a useful measure of computer performance through time is a challenge because the nature of the computer is changing in many ways. For example, some experts forecast that the emergence of grid computing and Web-based services will change information technology from assets that firms own—in the form of computers, software, and other devices—to a service they purchase from utility providers.73

    2. Hedonic price indexes provide a proven method for adjusting for quality differences in computers across time. Using this method requires improved performance measures for computers and computer components.74

  1. Microprocessors are the single largest semiconductor expenditure in computers, and there are some signs that quality-adjusted price declines for this input have recently slowed significantly. This slowdown appears to be linked to a recently struck “brick wall” that now limits continuing improvements in microprocessor operating speeds.75 If this continues, it suggests the pos-

73

See Mike Nelson, “Moving Computing to the Grid,” in National Research Council, The Telecommunications Challenge: Changing Technologies and Evolving Policies, Charles W. Wessner, ed., Washington, D.C.: The National Academies Press, 2006. Also, see Nicholas Carr, “The End of Corporate Computing,” MIT Sloan Management Review, 46(3):67-73, 2005.

74

Gregory Chow pioneered the use of hedonic techniques for constructing a constant quality index of computer prices in research conducted at IBM. See Gregory C. Chow, “Technological Change and the Demand for Computers,” American Economic Review, 57(5):117-130, December 1967. In 1985, BEA incorporated constant quality price indexes for computers and peripheral equipment constructed by IBM into the National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA). The economic interpretation of these indexes by Jack Triplett brought the rapid decline of computer prices to the attention of a very broad audience. See Jack Triplett, “The Economic Interpretation of Hedonic Methods,” Survey of Current Business, 66(1):36-40, January 1986. Triplett has also provided exhaustive surveys of research on hedonic price indexes for computers. See, for example, Jack Triplett, Handbook on Hedonic Indexes and Quality Adjustments in Price Indexes: Special Application to Information Technology Products, Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 2004.

75

Improvements in microprocessor clock rates have historically been the largest single contributing factor to declines in prices for these components. For evidence on these points see Kenneth Flamm, “Economics of Innovation in the Microprocessor Industry,” Working Paper, University of Texas at Austin, February 2006. Flamm’s analysis is confirmed by recent Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS)

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

sibility that we may soon see a lessening of the pace of price declines for computers, which ultimately will have negative economic implications for the wider economy as a whole.

Recommendations
  1. The computer component industry has developed a variety of formal and informal measures to gauge the relative performance of its products. Further development of these measures and subsequent incorporation into the National Income and Product Accounts should enable improved analysis and policies to sustain the contributions of computers and computer components to economic growth.

  2. Wider adoption of technology roadmaps and enhanced government-industry cooperation can improve our capacity to reinforce the growth path predicted by Moore’s Law in the computer and computer component industries.

  3. Given the apparent slowdown in microprocessor speeds, accelerated research investment in methods and tools to lessen the cost of writing software that can utilize multiple computer processor cores “in parallel” would seem to be a priority, particularly given the potentially large economic payoffs in maintaining the pace of technological advance in IT.76

E.
SOFTWARE’S CRUCIAL ROLE

Findings
  1. Software is the means by which we interface with the information and communications technologies that underpin the modern economy.

    1. The United States economy is highly dependent on software, with businesses, public utilities, and consumers among those integrated within complex software systems.

    2. Computer systems, such as those used by businesses, integrate software and hardware with detailed knowledge about the context of the application. A workforce that understands both the nature of business processes

data showing that there has been a substantial slowdown in the rate of decline of prices for microprocessors. This is NAICS 334413 (Semiconductor and Related Device Manufacturing) and can be found in the BLS detailed report on the Producer Price Index (PPI). Accessed at <http://www.bls.gov/ppi/ppidr_t01-09.pdf>.

76

A recent National Academies study by the Committee on the Future of Supercomputing identifies this problem. See National Research Council, Getting Up to Speed: The Future of Supercomputing, op. cit.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

as well as information technology is necessary to develop and maintain such systems.

  1. The structure of software is highly complex. While better software permits operations at unparalleled levels of sophistication, this complexity also creates significant economic and national security vulnerabilities.

    1. As software has become more complex, safeguarding it has become more difficult. Attacks against software—in the form of both network intrusions and infection attempts—have also grown substantially in recent times. Moreover, the economic impact of such attacks is increasingly significant.

    2. Thus, a major challenge lies in creating software code that is relatively error free, virus-resistant, robust against change, and capable of scaling reliably to incredibly high volumes while ensuring that it can integrate seamlessly and reliably to many other software systems in real time.

  1. Tracking software prices and aggregate investments in software, and hence their impact on the economy, is a challenge given the unique and embedded nature of software.77

    1. Software is complex in structure, and the market for software is different from that of other goods and services. Software can be easily duplicated (often at low cost) and the service life of software is often hard to anticipate. The nature and functions of software also evolve over time, requiring the development of quality-adjusted price indexes for various types of software.

    2. In addition, most of the nation’s software capability is embedded in firms that are not classified as the software industry. These sectors include financial services, health care informatics, telecommunications, defense, aerospace, and automobiles. Tracking the value contribution of software in these sectors is challenging because the capability is thoroughly integrated into the organization, and despite this, that capability depends closely on technologies developed in the information technology sectors, including software, computers, and IT services.

    3. The Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) distinguishes among three types of software—prepackaged, custom, and own-account software. Prepackaged software is sold or licensed in standardized form and is delivered in packages or electronic files downloaded from the Internet.

77

For a detailed overview of the role of IT in the national accounts and methods used by BEA (and BLS) to construct appropriate prices, see Bruce Grimm, Brent R. Moulton, and David B. Wasshausen, “Information-Processing Equipment and Software in the National Accounts,” in Measuring Capital in the New Economy, Carol Corrado, John Haltiwanger, and Daniel Sichel, eds., Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 2005, pp. 363-402.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

Custom software is tailored to the specific application of the user and is delivered along with analysis, design, and programming services required for customization. Own-account software consists of software created for a specific application. However, at present, only price indexes for prepackaged software hold performance constant.78

  1. Given that only the prices of prepackaged software are adequately represented in the official system of price statistics, software prices are in a statistical blind spot. A major challenge lies in constructing constant quality price indexes for custom and own-account software.

  1. Open-source software is promising. Open-source software development has proven to be a significant and successful way of creating software that is more robust.79

    1. The policy challenge lies in fostering incentives for individuals to develop basic software components through open-source coordination, while ensuring that once they are built, they will be widely available at low cost so that future development can be stimulated.80

    2. Measuring open-source software in the national accounts is a challenge given the distribution in prices and value-added services and the need to separate business services from software.

  1. Software suffers from relatively slow measured productivity growth. In contrast to trends found in other information technology sectors, productivity growth in software development does not appear to be as significant.

    1. There is limited progress in automating the production of software. Software writing—particularly at the creative or high end—remains in many respects a cottage industry.

    2. Complementarities among skill sets needed to develop software mean that scaling up and speeding up production are difficult.

78

Robert P. Parker and Bruce T. Grimm, “Recognition of Business and Government Expenditures on Software as Investment: Methodology and Quantitative Impacts, 1959-1998,” Washington, D.C.: Bureau of Economic Analysis, November 2000.

79

For example, Apple Inc. notes that “using Open Source methodology makes Mac OS X a more robust, secure operating system, as its core components have been subjected to the crucible of peer review for decades. Any problems found with this software can be immediately identified and fixed by Apple and the Open Source community.” See <http://www.apple.com/opensource/>. For an empirical analysis showing fewer and more rapid bug fixes with open-source software, see Jennifer Kuan, “Open Source Software as Lead User’s Make or Buy Decision: A Study of Open and Closed Source Quality,” Palo Alto, CA: Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research, 2002.

80

See comments by Hal Varian in National Research Council, Software, Growth, and the Future of the U.S. Economy, op. cit.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
  1. The software workforce is highly differentiated and includes computer scientists and engineers of varying caliber. Increasingly, this labor pool is dispersed around the world.

    1. There are a relatively small number of high-quality software developers. Industry participants suggest that there are only a very limited number of such “superstars”—those with productivity that is 20 to 100 times better than that of average software developers—and that this talent is scattered worldwide.81

    2. Competition for high-quality software developers is accelerating. The international competition for this limited pool of highly skilled labor is acute and is expected to accelerate.82

  1. Software and hardware play interdependent roles in enhancing the productivity of information technology. More widespread use of multiple-core processors, needed to overcome the apparent slowdown of processor clock rates, will require additional software development.

    1. The apparent slowdown in improvement of processor clock rates means that much continuing price-performance improvement in computer hardware will increasingly require harnessing the power of microprocessors with multiple cores. Making effective use of such multi-core processors is likely to be less difficult for business computers (like servers) that serve applications to many different users and can make easy use of this greater processor power to serve more users.

    2. However, harnessing multiple processor cores on a single more powerful application is much more complex, and requires writing or reengineering software to split it up into multiple threads that can operate in parallel.

Recommendations
  1. Software price indexes, especially for own-account and custom software, must be upgraded to hold software performance constant. Without adjustment for quality, these indexes present a distorted picture of software prices as well as software output and investment.

    1. Advances in developing software price indexes, including current work by BEA on function points, hedonic techniques, and other methodologies, should be supported.83 These advances can improve statistical

81

William Raduchel, “The Economics of Software,” in National Research Council, Software, Growth, and the Future of the U.S. Economy, op. cit.

82

Wayne Rosing, “Hiring Software Talent,” in National Research Council, Software, Growth, and the Future of the U.S. Economy, op. cit.

83

BEA has recently launched a software pricing project for custom and own-account software using function points. Work by Q/P Management Group and the Analysis Group is expected to produce new price indexes for custom and own-account software for the U.S. national accounts. A function

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

information on firm investments in customized software applications such as own-account and custom software.84

  1. Adoption of common standards across the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) and beyond should also be further encouraged. Wider use of standards can improve our knowledge about investments in software in what is a global industry and facilitate the tracking of software outsourcing.85

  2. Active and informed participation by standards organizations such as the National Institute of Standards and Technology (NIST), in close consultation with industry associations, are necessary if the United States is to participate effectively in the process.

  1. The United States needs to foster the expert workforce needed to develop and maintain the computer systems so critical to the nation’s economy and security.

    1. Developing the basis for a better-trained workforce begins with strengthening K-12 education. At the secondary level and beyond, scholarships are needed to attract more U.S. students, including women and minorities, to pursue training in computer science and related fields.86

    2. More adaptive immigration policies are also required to attract and retain in the United States foreign students who have been trained in American universities—especially those who are exceptionally talented.87 In addition, visa restrictions that prevent or impede highly talented software developers from working in the United States should be revised.

    3. The nature of the market for software superstars is poorly understood.88 Given the increasingly apparent “bottleneck” role of software development in limiting the continued growth in the New Economy, a major research effort aimed at understanding the economics of the software industry and software labor markets would seem highly desirable.

point metric is a means of measuring software size and productivity. It uses functional, logical entities such as inputs, outputs, and inquiries that tend to relate more closely to the functions performed by the software. See John J. Marciniak, ed., Encyclopedia of Software Engineering, New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons, 1994, pp. 518-524.

84

David Wasshausen, “A BEA Perspective: Private Fixed Software Investment,” in National Research Council, Software, Growth, and the Future of the U.S. Economy, op. cit.

85

See comments by Dirk Pilat, “What is in the OECD Accounts and How Good is it?” in National Research Council, Software, Growth, and the Future of the U.S. Economy, op. cit.

86

NAS/NAE/IOM, Rising Above the Gathering Storm: Energizing and Employing America for a Brighter Economic Future, op. cit., Chapter 5.

87

National Research Council, Policy Implications of International Graduate Students and Post-doctoral Scholars in the United States, Washington, D.C.: The National Academies Press, 2005.

88

William Raduchel, “The Economics of Software,” in National Research Council, Software, Growth, and the Future of the U.S. Economy, op. cit.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
  1. Sustaining the productivity gains from information technology includes maintaining existing computer systems and, given the limited lifespan of such systems, investing in the development of future systems.

    1. Computer systems have a limited lifespan. Improved metrics are necessary if firms are to properly capitalize their software expenses, anticipate the liabilities at the end of the software system’s life cycle, and plan for future systems.

    2. Improvements in custom coding, software-oriented architecture, and Web-based services will be necessary to sustain the productivity gains from software.

    3. Interdisciplinary training that combines computer science with business management, finance, and other application fields is necessary to develop the expertise required to build and maintain the information technology systems of the future.

  1. The slowdown in the improvement of processor clock rate, which historically has been the focus for applications running on supercomputers, will soon become vastly more important on desktop computers containing new, multi-core microprocessors. Significant national investment in basic research on software development methodologies and tools for “parallelizing” applications to make use of multiple processors would seem to be a very worthwhile endeavor, with potentially significant economic impacts in maintaining the pace of the New Economy.89

F.
THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS CHALLENGE

Findings
  1. Communications technology is crucial for the rapid development and diffusion of the Internet, perhaps the most striking manifestation of information technology in the American economy. By storing, sorting, and distributing vast information very quickly and at very low cost over communications networks, the Internet may be potentially very important in the longer run for the continued growth in output and improved productivity of the United States and other knowledge economies.90 Communications equipment is also

89

As mentioned earlier, this problem was recently noted and a congruent recommendation made by the National Academies Committee on the Future of Supercomputing. See National Research Council, Getting Up to Speed: The Future of Supercomputing, op. cit. See also Kenneth Flamm, “The Coming IT Slowdown: Technological Roots and Economic Implications,” Working Paper, LBJ School of Public Policy, University of Texas, October 2005.

90

The rapid growth of the Internet (and particularly the World Wide Web) is captured by Metcalfe’s Law, which observes that the power of the network increases exponentially by the number of computers connected to it. This is because computers added to the network not only use it as a resource

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

an important market for semiconductors. Switching and terminal equipment rely heavily on semiconductor technology, so that product development in communications often reflects improvements in semiconductors.

  1. Advances in telecommunications equipment, however, are derived from a variety of sources. Technological advance in fiber optics, microwave broadcasting, and communications satellites, as well as for switches and routers that are used to send and receive data, have progressed at rates that in some cases outrun even the dramatic pace of semiconductor development.91 The convergence of these advanced technologies is a powerful source of innovation.

    1. For example, phenomenal progress has been made possible in part by advances in Dense Wavelength Division Multiplexing (DWDM), a technology that sends multiple signals over an optical fiber simultaneously. Installation of DWDM equipment, beginning in 1997, has doubled the transmission capacity of fiber optic cables every 6 to 12 months.

    2. Prices for communications gear have also been estimated to have fallen by about 8 to 10 percent per year between 1994 and 2000, although this is about half as fast as the decline in the price for computers.92

  1. The United States recently witnessed significant investments in telecommunications equipment, corresponding with the dot-com boom of the late 1990s. Much of this communications investment was in the form of the transmission gear, connecting data, voice, and video terminals to switching equipment.

    1. Investments in communications equipment in the United States are on par with those for computers. Over the course of the 1990s and continuing into the present decade, expenditure on communications has been around $100 billion per year, representing a little over 10 percent of total equipment investment in the United States.

but also potentially contribute resources available to other users, increasing the value and choices of the network.

91

The rate of improvement in the capacity of communications technology was first suggested by George Gilder, who observed that the maximum transmission rate for telecoms is tripling every year. This means that if computer power doubles every 18 months (per Moore’s Law), then communications power doubles every 6 months. See also estimates of 85 percent per annum growth since 1983 by Debra J. Aron, Ken Dunmore, and Frank Pampush, “Worldwide Wait? How the Telecom Act’s Unbundling Requirements Slow the Development of the Network Infrastructure,” Industrial & Corporate Change, 7(4):615-621, 1998.

92

Mark Doms, “The Record to Date: Quality Adjusted Prices for Equipment,” in National Research Council, The Telecommunications Challenge: Changing Technologies and Evolving Policies, op. cit.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
  1. At the same time, there have been large swings in the U.S. investment in communications, with investment in communications gear falling 35 percent during the recession of the early 2000s.

  1. Although massive investments in the nation’s high-capacity Internet backbone have created excess capacity in long-haul facilities, a variety of factors—regulation among them—have slowed the build-out of the crucial last mile.

    1. By creating highly technology-specific industry rules, and by attempting to promote competition by requiring incumbents to share the local loops of their network with rivals, the Telecommunications Act of 1996 may have, according to some experts, inadvertently inhibited investment needed to diffuse high-bandwidth access over the last mile.93

    2. While broadband adoption has grown quickly in recent years, demand for broadband adoption appears to be slowing. A recent survey by the Pew organization shows that 32 percent of the adult population in the United States does not use the Internet, a number that held steady for the first 6 months of 2005.94

    3. According to the International Telecommunications Union, the United States significantly lags other advanced nations in high-speed broadband access, ranking sixteenth in the world in broadband penetration in 2005.95 However, these data relate to diffusion to households, whereas information about diffusion to businesses (which has important consequences for productivity) is limited.

    4. Our limited knowledge about the scope of broadband diffusion and adoption inhibits policies needed to better capitalize on the nation’s

93

Robert Litan and Roger G. Noll, “The Uncertain Future of the Telecommunications Industry,” Brookings Working Paper, December 3, 2003, Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution. Interpretations vary on the impact of the 1996 Telecommunications Act. Some experts believe that competition for the provision of broadband was already taking place in most major downtown areas in many of the largest cities of the United States before the Telecommunications Act. See Glenn Woroch, “Local Network Competition,” in Handbook of Telecommunications Economics, Martin Cave, Sumit Majumdar, and Ingo Vogelsang, eds., New York, NY: Elsevier, 2002. Others believe that the Act did not deter the build-out of the nation’s cable network. For example, see Jonathan E. Nuechterlein and Philip J. Weiser, Digital Crossroads: American Telecommunications Policy in the Internet Age, Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press, 2005.

94

John B. Horrigan, “Broadband Adoption at Home in the United States: Growing but Slowing,” Pew Internet and American Life Project, paper presented to the 33rd Telecommunications Policy Research Conference, September 25, 2005.

95

The International Telecommunication Union (ITU) reports that in 2005 the five top nations for broadband network market penetration were Korea, Hong Kong, the Netherlands, Denmark, and Canada. The ITU ranked the United States sixteenth in broadband penetration. ITU Strategy and Policy Unit Newslog, August 8, 2005. Accessed at <http://www.itu.int/osg/spu/newslog/CategoryView,category,Broadband.aspx>.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

substantial investments in information technology and infrastructure, limiting the potential for sustained growth in the economy.

  1. Wireless broadband can help overcome some of the limitations associated with traditional wired broadband access—not least the costs associated with wiring the last mile.

    1. While wireless broadband has been in limited use to date due to relatively high subscriber costs and technological challenges such as those related to obstacle penetration, rapid advances in technology are likely to overcome such challenges.

    2. Some industry experts believe that the emerging WiMAX standard promises to resolve a number of problems that confront existing wireless protocols such as WiFi.96

  1. The convergence of data, voice, video, wireless, and public and private networks into an end-to-end infrastructure, now under way, is challenging business models and regulatory frameworks alike. The commoditization of information is ushering a major shift from distinct vertically integrated industries that are focused on particular products or services towards a more horizontal platform that supports the movement of content and application services moving across IT networks.97

    1. This convergence is changing the terms of competition across industries. While there was once a major separation between the telecom and cable industries, for example, these businesses are likely to overlap and offer similar kinds of services.

    2. Regulators face new challenges as telecommunications services are increasingly becoming blended, with voice, data, and video transmitted in commoditized packets over the air or through a wire. The end of “stovepiping” also poses new challenges for consumers.98 Consumers confronted with a proliferation of Internet services, operating systems, and devices may look for service that is integrated and easy to use.99

    3. Replacing “silo” or sector-specific communications regulation with a policy framework that address the emerging horizontal technology plat-

96

David Lippke, “The Wireless Wildcard,” in National Research Council, The Telecommunications Challenge: Changing Technologies and Evolving Policies, op. cit.

97

William Raduchel, “The End of Stovepiping,” in National Research Council, The Telecommunications Challenge: Changing Technologies and Evolving Policies, op. cit.

98

Stovepiping refers to the retrieval of information from unconnected databases—in particular the situation that exists when it is necessary to “climb out” of one database in order to climb down into another.

99

Lisa Hook, “Serving Consumers on Broadband,” in National Research Council, The Telecommunications Challenge: Changing Technologies and Evolving Policies, op. cit.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

forms is needed to complement the networked characteristic of the New Economy.100

  1. The value of intellectual property is increasingly recognized, and the use of patents has increased dramatically. Yet, businesses have faced serious challenges of protecting intellectual property in the era of digital distribution. Recently available technologies, for example, have allowed consumers to share music and content with each other for free.101 The trend towards improved security of intellectual property, such as the recent success of the iPod and related legitimate forms of on-line music diffusion, is encouraging and can help stimulate the creation of new content and applications.102

  2. The move towards virtualization, grid computing, and Web services is leading to a major shift in the nature of information technology assets from computers, software, and myriad related components that companies own to services that firms purchase from on-line utility providers.103

Recommendations
  1. The varying complexity and rates of technical innovation make the contribution of telecommunications equipment to productivity growth a challenge to measure. Current BEA methodologies for making intertemporal comparisons in price and quality understate true price declines in communications equipment because they do not fully track evolving technological changes.104

    1. For most of the 1990s, manufacturers focused on features such as greater port density, faster speeds, and support for an increasing number of communication protocols in designing new switches and routers. After the 2001 collapse in demand for telecommunications equipment, manufacturers began to differentiate their products in new and innovative ways that are difficult to quantify on a quality-adjusted basis. Better data and analysis are needed to get a clear idea of what happened with regard to

100

Peter Tenhula, “Technological Change and Economic Opportunity: The View from the Federal Communications Commission,” in National Research Council, The Telecommunications Challenge: Changing Technologies and Evolving Policies, op. cit.

101

However, in the case of the music-swapping service Napster, a U.S. federal appeals court ruled in 2001 that the file-sharing Internet company must stop trading in copyrighted material.

102

Steve Metalitz, “The View from the Copyright Industries,” in National Research Council, The Telecommunications Challenge: Changing Technologies and Evolving Policies, op. cit.

103

Nicholas G. Carr, “The End of Corporate Computing,” op. cit.

104

BEA estimated that prices for communications gear fell an average of 3.2 percent per year between 1994 and 2000. Recent analysis by Marc Doms however suggests that communications equipment prices actually fell about 8 to 10 percent over that period. Mark Doms, “Communications Equipment: What has Happened to Prices?” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper, 2003-15.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

technological change in and prices of communications equipment from 2001 on.

  1. Valuing the improvements built into new switches and routers is difficult. While the Producer Price Index has tried to address some of these changes using hedonic techniques, data that consistently identify important current period product characteristics and transaction prices are not yet readily available.105 Research into alternative quality valuation techniques and improved data transparency is required to respond to the technological changes in telecommunications equipment. BEA and other statistical agencies require increased funding to follow evolving trends in the communications arena with more accuracy.

  1. As noted above with regard to software, greater attention to standards and the national and international process of their establishment is required. The economic stakes of standard setting are of great consequence. Some nations and regions see standards as a competitive tool and devote substantial resources to this end. The role and resources of the National Institute of Standards and Technology have to be seen in this light. The standard-making process must be recognized as a key component of U.S. competitiveness and provided commensurate resources and policy attention.

    1. Uncertainty created by a multiplicity of standards and a lack of clarity in regulatory policy are retarding progress in the growth of wireless and fiber networks needed to convey this commoditized information to the curb.106

    2. Technical standards, especially for wireless devices, are an important element in sustaining U.S. success in the global economy. Without effective standard-making capabilities and active U.S. participation in international standard-making bodies, the United States will not be able to maximize its advantages.107

  1. The supply as well as the demand side of the market for high-speed Internet access needs to be elaborated. While international comparisons show that U.S. broadband adoption for households lags that of other countries, relatively little is known about factors that affect the broadband adoption path

105

For additional perspective on the types of technological changes in telecom equipment that, at least conceptually, could be valued in a hedonic model, see Michael Holdway, “Confronting the Challenge of Estimating Constant Quality Price Indexes for Telecommunications Equipment in the Producer Price Index,” Bureau of Economic Analysis Working Paper, 2002.

106

See Action D-4 on ensuring ubiquitous broadband Internet access in NAS/NAE/IOM, Rising Above the Gathering Storm: Energizing and Employing America for a Brighter Economic Future, op. cit.

107

See National Research Council, Standards, Conformity Assessment, and Trade into the 21st Century, Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 1995.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

in the United States, particularly for businesses. Further data are required to understand the scope and nature of broadband use by businesses, and more study is required to understand why a significant percentage of households are not linked to the computer and Internet culture that is central to the new, more productive U.S. economy.108

  1. Revising outdated regulation and addressing issues of security and intellectual property protection are necessary for the nation to realize productivity gains from advances in communications technology.

    1. To address the technology convergence now under way, sector-specific telecom regulation—for radio, CDs and DVDs, television, telephony, and mobile telephony—must be replaced with a more horizontal (as opposed to a vertically stovepiped) regulatory regime.

    2. Internet-based services, through such means as grid computing, have the potential to improve productivity. Improved security in the broadband network, which stands as a major obstacle to more widespread use of the technology, has to be addressed.

    3. Developing a legitimate market for copyrighted materials over broadband—for entertainment, software, services, video games, research and reference works—is needed for the long-term viability of these industries.

G.
GLOBALIZATION AND OFFSHORING

Findings
  1. Rapid progress in information and communications technologies combined with continuing efforts to liberalize international trade and investment in services, have increased the tradability of services and created new types of tradable services.109 This has led to a new wave of globalization in the services sector, with offshoring of particular types of services now becoming increasingly common.

  2. The development of the Internet, in particular, has generated great economic opportunity, facilitated growth, and improved peoples’ lives in many ways. The Internet is also making possible new forms of business organization.

108

John B. Horrigan, “Broadband Adoption at Home in the United States: Growing but Slowing,” op. cit.

109

Desirée van Welsum and Xavier Reif, “Potential Offshoring: Evidence from Selected OECD Countries,” OECD-DSTI-ICCP, July 2005.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
  1. The declining cost of computing and communications is changing the structure of industrial organizations—replacing vertically integrated industries with newly economical horizontal platforms.110

  2. A new model for value delivery to businesses is based on an intelligent infrastructure, where this infrastructure spans the globe. Here the network becomes a repository of intelligence across a broad spectrum of applications, such as caching, security, multicasting, and network management.111

  1. Greater horizontal integration across the globe created by faster and cheaper information and communications technologies is opening new opportunities for U.S. firms to compete worldwide.

    1. The globalization of IT hardware and software research, production, and trade, as well as new competition from lower-wage producers, have helped reduce IT prices and should contribute to technological advance, helping to maintain Moore’s Law.112 These, in turn, have facilitated the wider adoption of information technologies, making available the efficiencies that arise from their use.113

    2. From the perspective of many firms, cost savings through the outsourcing of research and production offshore provides a compelling business motive. It has rapidly become “best practice” for the business plans of new high-technology manufacturing and service companies.114

  1. Globalization is also giving rise to a shift in the comparative advantage of nations, raising major policy challenges—including questions concerning national competency, capacity, and autonomy in strategic technologies.115

    1. Access to low-cost, highly trained workers located around the world and the advantages of round-the-clock development cycles—made possible by low-cost computing and communications—have led to the relocation abroad of many business functions that can be outsourced. This phenom-

110

See comments by William Raduchel, “The End of Stovepiping,” in National Research Council, The Telecommunications Challenge: Changing Technologies and Evolving Policies, op. cit.

111

David S. Isenberg, “Rise of the Stupid Network,” Computer Telephony, pp. 16-26, August 1997.

112

24/7 research cycles and larger R&D teams made possible by less expensive skilled labor can accelerate research and product cycles. See Businessweek, “The Rise of India,” December 8, 2005.

113

Catherine Mann, High-tech and the Globalization of America, op. cit.

114

See comments by Jack Harding, “Current Trends and Implications: An Industry View,” in National Research Council, Software, Growth, and the Future of the U.S. Economy, op. cit. See also recent comments by Michael Mortiz, a prominent venture capitalist, who notes that “we can barely imagine investing in a company without at least asking what their plans are for India.” See Business-week, “The Rise of India,” op. cit.

115

See the recent findings by the National Academies’ Committee on Materials Research and Development in National Research Council, Globalization of Materials R&D: Time for a National Strategy, Washington, D.C.: The National Academies Press, 2005.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

enon is popularly known as “offshoring.” In addition to the moving of existing jobs to other countries, another dimension of offshoring is likely to be the creation of new service jobs in countries other than the United States—a trend that will be difficult to measure.

  1. By diffusing technology and research capabilities around the world, globalization enables other countries, including newly emerging econo-mies like China and India, to pursue technological leadership in key areas. Some analysts and business leaders believe that this diffusion of expertise abroad is eroding U.S. comparative advantages in high-technology innovation and manufacturing.116

  2. For the United States, the economic and strategic risks associated with offshoring include a loss of within-country expertise and future talent, dependency on other countries for key technologies, and increased vulnerability to political and financial instabilities abroad.117

  3. The Internet enables trade in services to a greater extent than before. The types of jobs subject to offshoring are increasingly moving from low-end services (such as call centers and help desks) to higher-technology services (such as software and microchip design, business consulting, medical analysis, and drug development) where the United States has traditionally enjoyed a comparative advantage.

  4. These trends notwithstanding, some analysts believe that there are limits to near-term globalization. On the demand side, recent experience seems to reveal that offshoring is proving successful for businesses only in

116

Some recent studies have questioned whether “offshoring” is simply another form of trade with mutual benefits. David Levy, for example, argues that reducing wages through offshore outsourcing leads to wealth creation for shareholders but not necessarily for countries and employees, and that many displaced workers have difficulty “trading up” to higher-skilled jobs. The result, he noted, is the creation of global commodity markets for particular skills and a shift in the balance of market power among firms, workers, and countries. David L. Levy, “The New Global Political Economy,” Journal of Management Studies, 42(3):685, May 2005.

This caution has been echoed in industry. Andy Grove of Intel has noted that firms need to strike a balance between maximizing shareholder value and their obligation to U.S. workers who helped build the nation’s technology industry but who are now being replaced by cheaper labor. Forbes, “Grove Says U.S. Is Losing Its Edge in High-Tech Sector,” October 10, 2003. See also the discussion by William Bonvillian, “Offshoring Policy Options,” in National Research Council, Software, Growth, and the Future of the U.S. Economy, op. cit.

117

In his dissent from the mainstream economic consensus about outsourcing and globalization, Paul Samuelson has argued that the assumption that the laws of economics dictate that the U.S. economy will benefit in the long run from all forms of trade, including the outsourcing of call-center and software programming jobs abroad, is a “popular polemical untruth.” Trade does not always work to all parties’ advantage, according to Samuelson. See Paul Samuelson, “Where Ricardo and Mill Rebut and Confirm Arguments of Mainstream Economists Supporting Globalization,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(3), 2004.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

selected contexts due to operational and management limitations.118 On the supply side, some believe that there are only a limited number of low-wage knowledge workers abroad in the market today who possess the necessary language skills, technical qualifications, and related abilities needed for successful international collaboration.119 Even if these limits to near-term globalization hold true, it is not clear whether this condition will persist. Further research is necessary to estimate how quickly these limitations may be overcome.

Recommendations
  1. Although the offshoring phenomenon—particularly the offshoring of service-sector jobs—is a topic of much currency, the scope of the phenomenon remains to be adequately documented. Despite extensive media attention, there is relatively little hard information about the causes and impact of offshoring on manufacturing and service-sector employment in the United States or on other related economic and structural developments.120

    1. A sustained effort to measure the dimensions and implications of off-shoring is necessary for informed policymaking. Further research is needed to make adequate evaluations of the effects of outsourcing, including the impact of high-tech job creation abroad rather than in the United States.121 To overcome the lack of appropriate, adequate data for

118

According to the McKinsey Global Institute, internal barriers within firms, most notably operational issues, management attitude to offshoring, and structural issues can limit demand. Adding that external regulatory barriers also play a small role overall, it concludes that the “potential for global resourcing varies depending on the industry.” See McKinsey Global Institute, The Emerging Global Labour Market, Part I: “Demand for Offshore Talent and Sector Cases,” 2005.

119

McKinsey Global Institute, The Emerging Global Labour Market, Part II: “Synthesis of Findings: Supply of Offshore Talent,” 2005. Some statements about the numbers and qualifications of Indian and Chinese engineers may be overstated, while U.S. graduates and qualifications may be understated. See Gary Gereffi and Vivek Wadhwa, “Framing the Engineering and Outsourcing Debate: Placing the United States on a Level Playing Field with China and India,” Duke University School of Engineering, December 12, 2005.

120

While preliminary analysis has not found that outsourcing of business services has had much effect on the growth of the U.S. economy (Ralph Kozlow and Maria Borga, “Offshoring and the US Balance of Payments,” Washington, D.C.: Bureau of Economic Analysis, 2004), popular evaluations argue that the world of technology is becoming increasingly international (see, for example, Thomas Friedman, The World is Flat, New York, NY: Farrar Straus & Giroux, 2005).

121

The 2006 report of the Association for Computing Machinery’s Job Migration Task Force similarly finds that “while offshoring will increase, determining the specifics of this increase is difficult given the current quantity, quality, and objectivity of data available. Skepticism is warranted regarding claims about the number of jobs to be offshored and the projected growth of software industries in developing countries.” Association of Computing Machinery, “Globalization and Offshoring of Software,” William Aspray, Frank Mayadas, and Moshe Y. Vardi, eds., New York, NY, 2006. Lastly, assessments of jobs outsourced do not necessarily take into account the impact of foreign investment, increasingly for countries such as India and China, on U.S. employment.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

this analysis, the necessary resources should be made available to provide better information both to policymakers and to the general public about the evolution and performance of the American economy.

  1. In any event, we must recognize that the global competitive environment is shifting. According to several recent reports, the pace of global competition is accelerating and the United States will need to redouble support for existing strengths (e.g., research), strengthen proven commercialization programs, and experiment with new efforts.122

  1. To thrive in the globally competitive environment, the United States has to maintain its technological leadership. This requires continuing investments in the nation’s science and technology infrastructure. This, in turn, requires both substantial investments in science and technology education as well as experimentation with policy mechanisms that can capitalize on these investments.

    1. The United States’ current leadership in high technology draws from substantial federal investments starting in the postwar period in the nation’s science and technology infrastructure. Key elements of this policy have included building a system of research universities and attracting foreign talent though scholarships and by providing academic freedoms and research facilities not available elsewhere. This institutional capital has to be upgraded and adapted to new needs and opportunities if the United States is to maintain its leadership as a knowledge-based economy.

    2. U.S. information technology firms, and the U.S. economy, will forgo the benefits of leadership unless they can attract the best human resources, garner sufficient research funding, develop and support robust mechanisms for technology transfer,123 and maintain an internationally competitive business environment.

    3. Four specific steps to retain and develop the semiconductor industry and U.S. research capacity in this sector would include:

      1. Substantial additional research funding should be provided at the 10 percent per year recommended in the NAS/NAE/IOM report,

122

For example, see Council on Competitiveness, Innovate America: Thriving in a World of Challenge and Change, Washington, D.C., 2004.

123

In this regard, the recent flattening of research funding and the elimination of funding for new awards from the Advanced Technology Program are troubling. The recent NAS/NAE/IOM report, Rising Above the Gathering Storm: Energizing and Employing America for a Brighter Economic Future, op. cit., argues for additional R&D funding and new efforts to transition them to market. Previous Academy analysis, led by Intel’s Gordon Moore, documented the substantial positive accomplishments of the Advanced Technology Program. See National Research Council, The Advanced Technology Program: Assessing Outcomes, op. cit., pp. 87-98. The NRC study found the program’s industry-driven, cost-shared approach to funding promising technological opportunities to be effective. It also found a high standard for assessment. Indeed, the quality of the assessment lends credence to the program’s evaluation of its accomplishments.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

Rising Above the Gathering Storm,124 with particular emphasis on the physical sciences and engineering.

  1. U.S. policymakers would benefit from evaluations of current worldwide policy and programs in support of this enabling industry.125

  2. The federal government should continue to provide support for proven mechanisms to transfer technology and commercialize promising technologies.126

  3. The United States needs to adopt measures to encourage research in the United States, including providing an attractive business environment involving competitive tax regimes, infrastructure support, cooperative research programs, and generous tax credits for corporate R&D. These measures are essential to maintain a competitive advantage for the U.S. economy in the locational competition for high-technology industries.127

H.
NEW ARCHITECTURE FOR THE U.S. NATIONAL ACCOUNTS

Findings
  1. The U.S. national accounts were originally constructed to deal with issues arising from the Great Depression of the 1930s, and the basic architecture of the national accounts has not been substantially altered in 50 years. In the meantime, the success of monetary and fiscal policies has shifted the policy focus from stabilization of the economy to enhancing the economy’s growth potential. In addition, the economy is confronted with new challenges arising from rapid changes in technology and globalization.

  2. America’s economy is large and diverse, and it is not surprising that accounting for this vast range of economic activity requires a decentralized statistical system. The major agencies involved in generating the national accounts include the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) in the Department of Commerce, the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) in the Department of Labor, and the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

124

NAS/NAE/IOM, Rising Above the Gathering Storm: Energizing and Employing America for a Brighter Economic Future, op. cit.

125

The Board on Science, Technology, and Economic Policy has an analysis of foreign programs under way that is focused on best practices, Comparative Innovation Policy: Best Practice in National Technology Programs, under the direction of William Spencer.

126

National Research Council, The Advanced Technology Program: Assessing Outcomes, op. cit.

127

Similar priorities have been identified in Europe. See ESIA, “The European Semiconductor Industry 2005 Competitiveness Report,” op. cit.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
  1. The BEA has responsibility for the core system of accounts, the National Income and Product Accounts. The BLS generates employment statistics, wage and salary data, and productivity statistics, as well as almost all of the underlying price information. The Board of Governors produces the Flow of Funds Accounts, including balance sheets for major financial sectors. Many other agencies and private sector organizations provide source data for the national accounts.

    1. As an illustration, both BEA and BLS measure industry output. BEA’s estimates are used to allocate the GDP to individual industries. BLS generates its own estimates in arriving at measures of industry-level productivity growth. Unfortunately, the BEA and BLS estimates of industry output do not always agree.

    2. As a second illustration, the Board of Governors generates a measure of national saving from the income statements and balance sheets that comprise the Flow of Funds Accounts. BEA produces an estimate of national saving from the income and product accounts. Although both estimates agree that the saving rate has declined sharply over the past 20 years, they employ different data sources and sometimes arrive at conflicting results.

Recommendations
  1. The U.S. national accounts require a new architecture to guide the future development of this decentralized system. The National Income and Product Accounts, the productivity statistics, and the Flow of Funds have different origins, reflecting diverse objectives and data sources. However, they are intimately linked. An important motivation for developing a new architecture is to integrate the different components and make them as consistent as possible.128

  2. An important objective of the new architecture is to combine the data sources employed by BEA and BLS in order to arrive at a common set of estimates. This is a crucial ingredient in long-term projections of the U.S. economy that depend on the disparate trends in productivity in key industries, such as information technology producers and intensive users of information technology.

  3. Another goal of this new architecture is to bring the flow of funds and the national income accounts into consistency in order to provide better data for

128

More details about the new architecture are presented in Dale W. Jorgenson, J. Steven Landefeld, and William Nordhaus, eds., A New Architecture for the U.S. National Accounts, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 2006. Accessed at <http://www.nber.org/books/CRIW-naccts/index.html>.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

anticipating future financing needs of both public and private sectors.129 This proposed system of accounts integrates the National Income and Product Accounts with the productivity statistics generated by BLS and balance sheets produced by the Federal Reserve Board. The proposed system would feature GDP, as does the National Income and Product Accounts; however, GDP and domestic income are generated along with productivity growth. BEA’s accounts for reproducible assets and the U.S. International Investment Position are extended to encompass a balance sheet for the U.S. economy as a whole.

  1. The cost of capital for productive assets employed in the U.S. economy provides a unifying methodology for integrating the National Income and Product Accounts generated by BEA and the productivity statistics constructed by BLS.130 The next step is to develop a complete version of the BLS productivity statistics that is consistent with a new system of official industry accounts recently released by BEA.131

  2. To further explore these proposals for a new architecture, additional resources should be made available. The drivers of the U.S. economy have evolved, indeed shifted quite dramatically, and it is essential that a new architecture for the national accounts be put into place to better capture this new reality.132

129

The key elements of the new architecture are outlined in a “Blueprint for Expanded and Integrated U.S. Accounts,” by Dale W. Jorgenson and J. Steven Landefeld, 1995. Accessed at <http://post.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/jorgenson/papers/Blueprint_051905.pdf>.

130

A detailed set of productivity statistics for the United States is presented by Dale W. Jorgenson, Mun S. Ho, and Kevin J. Stiroh, Productivity, Volume 3: Information Technology and the American Growth Resurgence, op. cit.

131

Access at <http://www.bea.doc.gov/bea/newsrel/gdpindnewsrelease.htm>.

132

The BEA is currently working with the National Science Foundation on accounts for research and development that could ultimately lead to recognition of R&D investment and capital stocks. The results of this accounting should assist future evaluations of high-tech investment and its effects on the economy.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×

This page intentionally left blank.

Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 17
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 18
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 19
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 20
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 21
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 22
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 23
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 24
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 25
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 26
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 27
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 28
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 29
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 30
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 31
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 32
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 33
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 34
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 35
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 36
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 37
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 38
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 39
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 40
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 41
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 42
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 43
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 44
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 45
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 46
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 47
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 48
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 49
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 50
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 51
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 52
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 53
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 54
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 55
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 56
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 57
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 58
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 59
Suggested Citation:"II FINDINGS AND RECOMMENDATIONS, Findings and Recommendations." National Research Council. 2007. Enhancing Productivity Growth in the Information Age: Measuring and Sustaining the New Economy. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/11823.
×
Page 60
Next: III SUMMARY OF THE NRC CONFERENCES ON THE NEW ECONOMY, The NRC Conferences on the New Economy »
  1. ×

    Welcome to OpenBook!

    You're looking at OpenBook, NAP.edu's online reading room since 1999. Based on feedback from you, our users, we've made some improvements that make it easier than ever to read thousands of publications on our website.

    Do you want to take a quick tour of the OpenBook's features?

    No Thanks Take a Tour »
  2. ×

    Show this book's table of contents, where you can jump to any chapter by name.

    « Back Next »
  3. ×

    ...or use these buttons to go back to the previous chapter or skip to the next one.

    « Back Next »
  4. ×

    Jump up to the previous page or down to the next one. Also, you can type in a page number and press Enter to go directly to that page in the book.

    « Back Next »
  5. ×

    Switch between the Original Pages, where you can read the report as it appeared in print, and Text Pages for the web version, where you can highlight and search the text.

    « Back Next »
  6. ×

    To search the entire text of this book, type in your search term here and press Enter.

    « Back Next »
  7. ×

    Share a link to this book page on your preferred social network or via email.

    « Back Next »
  8. ×

    View our suggested citation for this chapter.

    « Back Next »
  9. ×

    Ready to take your reading offline? Click here to buy this book in print or download it as a free PDF, if available.

    « Back Next »
Stay Connected!