National Academies Press: OpenBook

Investing for Productivity and Prosperity (1994)

Chapter: WHY DO HURTLE RATES DIFFER?

« Previous: HURDLE RATES AND INVESTMENT DECISIONS
Suggested Citation:"WHY DO HURTLE RATES DIFFER?." National Research Council. 1994. Investing for Productivity and Prosperity. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9075.
×

both U.S. and Japanese firms (Poterba and Summers, 1993). The executives who answered their survey believe that, on average, U.S. firms have shorter time horizons than do their Japanese competitors.11 Although it is difficult to measure this effect precisely, these studies support the board’s view that Japanese firms invest more than their U.S. competitors do because they use lower hurdle rates in evaluating investment projects, suggesting that Japanese firms operate with systematically lower perceived risk. This raises two questions: Why are hurdle rates in the United States higher than elsewhere? What, if anything, can public policy do to reduce them?

WHY DO HURDLE RATES DIFFER?

Hurdle rates vary for three reasons: differences in the cost of funds, in the tax treatment of corporate capital, and between the cost of capital and the hurdle rate set by managers. Financial investors and corporate managers can have different perceptions of risk. Such differences will result in a divergence between the hurdle rate managers use and the cost of capital, which is the rate shareholders would like them to use. At various times during the past two decades, each of these factors has contributed to the differential between hurdle rates in the United States and Japan. Corporate managers can also have different objectives, especially regarding the weight given shareholder interests. This is illustrated by tax-exempt institutions owning a large part of the shares in some large companies, while in others, especially more technologically risky companies, the shareholders are nearly all taxpaying. In the latter case, the managers may feel it necessary to achieve higher pre-tax returns on investment.

Numerous academic studies have attempted to measure the cost of capital or the cost of funds in the United States and Japan (Frankel, in press; McCauley and Zimmer, 1989; Poterba, 1991). There is general agreement that in the early 1980s, largely because of differences in real interest rates and leverage ratios, Japanese firms faced a lower cost of

11

The board is not aware of any data on hurdle rates or time horizons in countries other than the United States and Japan, although there are data on profit rates albeit based on different accounting and tax systems. Robert Z. Lawrence has compared rates of return in several other nations. The board recognizes, however, that investment time horizons vary widely among companies and across sectors as well as internationally. In the United States, three types of companies appear to be exceptions to the generalization about short time horizons: 1) privately held companies, 2) companies in industries such as aircraft and pharmaceuticals that are dependent on very large, high-risk investments in new product development, and 3) entrepreneurial start-up firms. See National Academy of Engineering (1993) for a succinct statement of such differences, and see page 33 below.

Suggested Citation:"WHY DO HURTLE RATES DIFFER?." National Research Council. 1994. Investing for Productivity and Prosperity. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9075.
×

funds than did U.S. firms. This translated into a lower cost of capital for Japanese firms, because other components of the cost of capital, such as the tax treatment of corporate income, did not differ dramatically between the two countries. As national markets for fixed-income securities (government and corporate bonds) became more integrated during the 1980s, the disparity between the costs of borrowing in the two nations has declined to the point where there is little difference today. Floating exchange rates will have an important effect on the perceptions of longer term investors, who can see anticipated returns offset by declines in the value of their principal in the investor’s currency. Hedging is difficult over longer periods and is expensive, which is why residential housing mortgages, for example, tend to be financed domestically.

The integration of equity markets is moving much more slowly for the understandable reasons that equities are more numerous and more complicated and their integration requires a much greater information flow. Although the pace has quickened, U.S. assets in international mutual funds are still less than 2 percent of the total value of U.S. equities (Poterba and French, 1991).12 There is little doubt that integration on the equity side will continue, accelerate, and eventually eliminate cost of equity differences. Nevertheless, because tax laws in various countries may still differ, international integration of equity and debt markets will not necessarily equalize the costs of capital across countries.

The board is most concerned about persistent differences in the cost of equity because of its bearing on relative rates of investment in technology. Corporate investments in certain intangible assets such as research and development, new business development, and development of human capital or training are most often financed with equity, partly because they do not give rise in the short run to an easily visible asset that can be measured. As a result, they cannot be used to collateralize debt in the way that tangible assets can be used. In many industries, intangible investments are increasingly the decisive factor in establishing and maintaining a competitive position in an internationally competitive industry. Even in the absence of external markets, intangible investments are essential to raise growth rates and the standard of living. Furthermore, these types of investments tend to have long time horizons, so that a disadvantage in the cost of the particular kind of capital that is used to finance them has a bigger negative effect than it would have for invest-

12

The growth of intermediaries in both the debt and equity areas is likely to continue and accelerate, causing the process of integration to continue in this decade.

Suggested Citation:"WHY DO HURTLE RATES DIFFER?." National Research Council. 1994. Investing for Productivity and Prosperity. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9075.
×
Page 26
Suggested Citation:"WHY DO HURTLE RATES DIFFER?." National Research Council. 1994. Investing for Productivity and Prosperity. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/9075.
×
Page 27
Next: SOURCE OF THE COST OF EQUITY DISPARITY »
Investing for Productivity and Prosperity Get This Book
×
 Investing for Productivity and Prosperity
MyNAP members save 10% online.
Login or Register to save!

READ FREE ONLINE

  1. ×

    Welcome to OpenBook!

    You're looking at OpenBook, NAP.edu's online reading room since 1999. Based on feedback from you, our users, we've made some improvements that make it easier than ever to read thousands of publications on our website.

    Do you want to take a quick tour of the OpenBook's features?

    No Thanks Take a Tour »
  2. ×

    Show this book's table of contents, where you can jump to any chapter by name.

    « Back Next »
  3. ×

    ...or use these buttons to go back to the previous chapter or skip to the next one.

    « Back Next »
  4. ×

    Jump up to the previous page or down to the next one. Also, you can type in a page number and press Enter to go directly to that page in the book.

    « Back Next »
  5. ×

    Switch between the Original Pages, where you can read the report as it appeared in print, and Text Pages for the web version, where you can highlight and search the text.

    « Back Next »
  6. ×

    To search the entire text of this book, type in your search term here and press Enter.

    « Back Next »
  7. ×

    Share a link to this book page on your preferred social network or via email.

    « Back Next »
  8. ×

    View our suggested citation for this chapter.

    « Back Next »
  9. ×

    Ready to take your reading offline? Click here to buy this book in print or download it as a free PDF, if available.

    « Back Next »
Stay Connected!