National Academies Press: OpenBook

Statistical Issues in Allocating Funds by Formula (2003)

Chapter: 4. Components of Allocation Formula

« Previous: 3. Basic Features of Formula Allocation Program
Suggested Citation:"4. Components of Allocation Formula." National Research Council. 2003. Statistical Issues in Allocating Funds by Formula. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/10580.
×

4
Components of Allocation Formulas

As their name implies, formula allocation programs allocate funds to recipients (governments or individuals) via a formula. Many formulas depend on the need of the recipient, and it is also common for formulas to include measures of fiscal capacity. And it is not unusual for aid amounts to depend on local effort. These and other inputs are common components in many formulas; however, the manner in which they are operationalized and combined does differ. Appendix B, a review of 12 of the largest federal formula allocation programs explores these issues in relation to specific programs.

MEASURES OF NEED

In theory, the resources needed by a recipient government in order to provide a target level of services depend both on the number of individuals eligible for the services and on the cost of providing them to each eligible individual. Generally, both of these components of need must be estimated. For example, the goal of the State Children’s Health Insurance Program (SCHIP) is to encourage states to establish insurance programs that cover children in families who are not eligible for Medicaid and for whom private insurance is prohibitively costly. Thus, aid under SCHIP depends on the estimated number of children who are not eligible for Medicaid and who do not have private insurance. Importantly, the cost of providing health care to each uninsured child varies by state and, if possible,

Suggested Citation:"4. Components of Allocation Formula." National Research Council. 2003. Statistical Issues in Allocating Funds by Formula. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/10580.
×

this cross-state variation should be reflected in aid amounts. But the true cost of insuring each eligible child will not be known and must be estimated.

Many aid formulas include ad hoc adjustments for variation in need. For example, to compensate for geographic differences in prevailing salaries and thereby in the cost of education, the Title I, Part A, grants to local education agencies formula includes state per-pupil expenditure (PPE) as one factor in determining the allocation (Brown, 2002). However, to our knowledge no existing school aid formula includes cost adjustments that are closely linked to evidence on the costs of providing particular services. There is general agreement that aid formulas should account for differences in costs, but generally they do not because developing cost estimates is extremely difficult and somewhat contentious. For example, although differences in PPE reflect relative costs, they also reflect variations in local wealth and commitment to education.

The SCHIP and Title I education examples highlight the important issue of whether aid should compensate primarily for costs that are beyond the control of decision makers in the recipient jurisdictions. If compensation is also influenced by controllable costs, the aid formula could generate perverse or undesirable incentives. For example, in SCHIP the method used to estimate the number of eligible children must be designed to avoid penalizing states for the success of the program (Czajka and Jabine, 2002). Also, if administrative data are used to estimate the number of eligible children or the cost per eligible child, these data must be chosen so that they are immune to manipulation.

A critical task for researchers is to compare the results of the alternative methodologies with the goal of developing consensus estimates of need. Duncombe and Lukemeyer (2002) provide a superb model of the style of research that must be produced.

MEASURES OF FISCAL CAPACITY

Measures of fiscal capacity are the second shared component of aid formulas. While per capita personal income is the most commonly used measure of fiscal capacity, other measures are more consistent with the goals of individual aid programs (Tannenwald, 1999; Downes and Pogue, 2002). For example, Downes and Pogue (1994) and Ladd (1994) agree that, if the goal of the aid program is to close the gap between need and effort and thereby reduce fiscal disparities, capacity measures based on the representa-

Suggested Citation:"4. Components of Allocation Formula." National Research Council. 2003. Statistical Issues in Allocating Funds by Formula. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/10580.
×

tive tax system (RTS), variants of which are used in state-level school aid programs and in the Canadian equalization program, should be used. The use of RTS-style measures of capacity ensures that all localities receiving aid will be able to finance a basic package of public services by levying average tax rates. Thus, no recipient governments will be at a competitive disadvantage (Ladd, 1994).

If the goal is redistribution of economic well-being or equal treatment of economic equals, the appropriate choice is a capacity measure that is based on an adjusted measure of income, for example, the total taxable resources (TTR) measure of capacity that is used in the community mental health services block grant and substance abuse block grant programs. TTR is based on the rationale that if the objective of aid is to redistribute from rich to poor or is to promote the evenhanded treatment of individuals whose economic circumstances are the same, the measure of capacity should reflect the cumulative ability of the residents of a locality receiving aid to pay taxes (Tannenwald, 1999). Using such a measure of capacity ensures that localities with equal abilities to pay taxes for public services will be treated equally and that localities with less ability to pay will get more aid. TTR is preferred to per capita income because it provides a more comprehensive measure of ability to pay. For example, accrued capital gains are included in TTR.

Any measure of capacity must be estimated, usually at a refined level of geographic and temporal resolution. The difficulties of generating income estimates for small areas are well known (National Research Council, 2001). The estimation problems become more daunting when adjustments need to be made for the extent to which taxes can be exported (shifted to non-residents) (Bradbury and Ladd, 1985; Downes and Pogue, 1994). Even capacity measures derived using the RTS methodology can be subject to large errors. Taylor et al. (2002) document some of the measurement problems that arise in the Canadian context; Tannenwald (1999, 2001) provides graphic evidence of the difficulty of generating state-level measures of fiscal capacity using the RTS methodology.

MEASURING EFFORT

A measure of effort is the final component common to many aid formulas. Recall that effort is measured by the revenues raised at the state or local level and spent on providing the service for which aid is provided. Effort measures are central elements in matching aid formulas, since for

Suggested Citation:"4. Components of Allocation Formula." National Research Council. 2003. Statistical Issues in Allocating Funds by Formula. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/10580.
×

most recipient jurisdictions the amount of aid is a (possibly variable) percentage of effort. Effort is also an important part of any aid formula that imposes a minimum effort requirement.

It would seem that effort is the component of an aid formula that is easiest to measure using direct information. Local tax rates are readily observable, as is spending on the service for which aid is being provided. However, measuring effort is not quite so straightforward. If aid amounts depend on spending on the targeted services, the recipient government has a strong incentive to overstate effort by classifying spending on other services as spending on the targeted services.1 Similar incentives to overstate effort operate if aid is contingent on minimum effort. Nevertheless, of the three shared components of aid formulas, effort can be measured with the smallest error.

COMBINING COMPONENTS

Most formulas combine two or more measures of need, fiscal capacity, and effort. Appendix B provides examples of the varied ways in which these measures are combined. Ideally, for programs with explicit goals, components should be combined to target these goals (Downes and Pogue, 2002); however, frequently there is not such a tight link. No matter how a formula is constructed, the choice of a particular combination of the components will influence how they interact.

A simple example helps clarify how errors in the measurement or estimation of the different components of an aid formula can interact. Chapter 2 presents a formula showing how components might be combined to close the gap between need and effort.

Errors in the number of eligibles (n), the level of spending per eligible individual needed to achieve the target service level (F), the cost index that adjusts for interlocality differences in the cost per eligible individual of providing given public services (C), or the fiscal capacity of the recipient jurisdiction (V) will produce discrepancies between the actual and desired aid distributions.

Reducing the error in measuring one component may not produce an improvement. Suppose, for example, that fiscal capacity is measured with-

1  

In the rare instances in which aid amounts are reduced by increased local effort, the recipient governments might attempt to understate effort by hiding expenditures or using funding mechanisms that are not counted as part of local effort.

Suggested Citation:"4. Components of Allocation Formula." National Research Council. 2003. Statistical Issues in Allocating Funds by Formula. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/10580.
×

out error but that the errors in estimating the number of eligibles and the cost per eligible are negatively correlated. The aid distributed might then be relatively close to the desired distribution. Reducing the error in estimating the number of eligibles while making no improvement in estimating the cost per eligible could result in an aid distribution that lines up less well with the desired distribution.

Changes in the aid distribution resulting from proposed improvements in the measurement of one or more components should be evaluated. Evaluations should include a study of how the relations between formula outputs (allocations) and inputs (measures of need, fiscal capacity, and effort) are affected by the change, taking into account the effects of hold-harmless provisions and other special features of the allocation process.

Suggested Citation:"4. Components of Allocation Formula." National Research Council. 2003. Statistical Issues in Allocating Funds by Formula. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/10580.
×
Page 35
Suggested Citation:"4. Components of Allocation Formula." National Research Council. 2003. Statistical Issues in Allocating Funds by Formula. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/10580.
×
Page 36
Suggested Citation:"4. Components of Allocation Formula." National Research Council. 2003. Statistical Issues in Allocating Funds by Formula. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/10580.
×
Page 37
Suggested Citation:"4. Components of Allocation Formula." National Research Council. 2003. Statistical Issues in Allocating Funds by Formula. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/10580.
×
Page 38
Suggested Citation:"4. Components of Allocation Formula." National Research Council. 2003. Statistical Issues in Allocating Funds by Formula. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/10580.
×
Page 39
Next: 5. Special Features of Formula Allocations »
Statistical Issues in Allocating Funds by Formula Get This Book
×
Buy Paperback | $53.00 Buy Ebook | $42.99
MyNAP members save 10% online.
Login or Register to save!
Download Free PDF

In 2000, the federal government distributed over $260 billion of funding to state and local governments via 180 formula programs. These programs promote a wide spectrum of economic and social objectives, such as improving educational outcomes and increasing accessibility to medical care, and many are designed to compensate for differences in fiscal capacity that affect governments’ abilities to address identified needs. Large amounts of state revenues are also distributed through formula allocation programs to counties, cities, and other jurisdictions. Statistical Issues in Allocating Funds by Formula identifies key issues concerning the design and use of these formulas and advances recommendations for improving the process. In addition to the more narrow issues relating to formula design and input data, the book discusses broader issues created by the interaction of the political process and the use of formulas to allocate funds.

Statistical Issues in Allocating Funds by Formula is only up-to-date guide for policymakers who design fund allocation programs. Congress members who are crafting legislation for these programs and federal employees who are in charge of distributing the funds will find this book indispensable.

  1. ×

    Welcome to OpenBook!

    You're looking at OpenBook, NAP.edu's online reading room since 1999. Based on feedback from you, our users, we've made some improvements that make it easier than ever to read thousands of publications on our website.

    Do you want to take a quick tour of the OpenBook's features?

    No Thanks Take a Tour »
  2. ×

    Show this book's table of contents, where you can jump to any chapter by name.

    « Back Next »
  3. ×

    ...or use these buttons to go back to the previous chapter or skip to the next one.

    « Back Next »
  4. ×

    Jump up to the previous page or down to the next one. Also, you can type in a page number and press Enter to go directly to that page in the book.

    « Back Next »
  5. ×

    Switch between the Original Pages, where you can read the report as it appeared in print, and Text Pages for the web version, where you can highlight and search the text.

    « Back Next »
  6. ×

    To search the entire text of this book, type in your search term here and press Enter.

    « Back Next »
  7. ×

    Share a link to this book page on your preferred social network or via email.

    « Back Next »
  8. ×

    View our suggested citation for this chapter.

    « Back Next »
  9. ×

    Ready to take your reading offline? Click here to buy this book in print or download it as a free PDF, if available.

    « Back Next »
Stay Connected!