National Academies Press: OpenBook

The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems (1994)

Chapter: Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government

« Previous: International Environmental Law and Industrial Ecology
Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×

The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. 1994.

Pp. 123-133. Washington, DC:

National Academy Press.

Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government

MATTHEW WEINBERG, GERGORY EYRING, JOE RAGUSO, and DAVID JENSEN

There is nothing more difficult . . . than to take the lead in introducing a new order of things.

Niccolo Machiavelli, The Prince

The relentless pace of technical and industrial advancement over the last century has fundamentally transformed the relationship between human society and the natural world. As the scope and range of human activities have expanded exponentially, profound and possibly irreversible environmental changes have been set in motion.1 For the first time in history, humankind can potentially alter the basic biophysical cycles of the earth.

Modem social systems have clearly broken away from the patterns of global ecological stability that existed during the 2 million years when humans lived in small nomadic bands (Ponting, 1990). But realistically there can be no turning back. While some believe that humanity's capacity for technical and economic progress is virtually boundless, the fact that human activities are now resulting in materials flows commensurate with those of nature should give one pause. Human activities are estimated to release several times as much mercury, nickel, arsenic, and vanadium to the environment as do natural processes, and more than 300 times as much lead (Galloway, 1982; see also Ayres, 1992). Concentrations of carbon dioxide in the atmosphere are increasing at a rate 30 to 100 times faster than observed in the climatic record; methane concentrations are increasing 400 times faster than historically (U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment, 1991a).

The challenges for our institutions of governance in addressing emerging en-

NOTE: The views expressed here are those of the authors alone and do not necessarily reflect those of the Office of Technology Assessment.

Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×

vironmental threats are indeed formidable. Traditional formulas of environmental management will no longer suffice. The reactive strategies of remediation and ''end-of-pipe" modification will have to be supplanted by new strategies and approaches. Systematic changes are needed in materials use, production processes, product formulation, product use, and disposal practices.

The evolving concept of industrial ecology could serve as a significant catalyst in transforming societal patterns of production and consumption. 2 Although at first glance the term industrial ecology appears to be an oxymoron, the notion of connectivity and interdependence that it embodies is extremely important. Interdependence is the dominant phenomenon of our age. With elaborate webs of production now stretching across the globe, the economic destinies of nations are closely intertwined. 3 Since these production networks draw on the natural resource endowments of countries around the world, our economic activities, regardless of how localized they appear, are becoming more closely tied to global ecological disruption4 (Wyckoff and Roop, 1992). Tighter economic linkages among nations are accentuating the world's environmental interdependence.

Societies can no longer separate economic imperatives from ecological imperatives. Economic productivity cannot be improved if the natural ecosystems on which the economy depends are undermined. Industrial enterprises need to create the same strong linkages at the postconsumer end of our economies that exist at the front end. Today's highly efficient one-way systems of providing goods and services must give way to circular systems of production. Use of both products and product waste streams needs to be optimized (Frosch, 1992). At all stages of production and consumption, actors must shape activities to minimize both resource use and waste generation. A true systems view of our industrial activities, and the impact of those activities on the environment, is required. This implies a fundamental reorientation of both the principles of product design and the institutional arrangements that govern the delivery of goods and services.

Yet, given the complexity and diversity of modem industrial economies, such a change in outlook is not readily achieved. Government thus has a pivotal role to play in ensuring that such a systems perspective is integrated into its programs of research and education, as well as its regulatory and fiscal policies.

BARRIERS TO CHANGE

Like physical systems, political, social, and economic systems are subject to inertia. Political barriers to change usually mirror broader societal barriers. As an illustration, families of technologies that become integral to the workings of societies tend to remain dominant for many decades. Trains, for example, were the dominant transport system for more than 70 years until they were displaced by trucks and automobiles, which have been dominant for much of this century and are not likely to be displaced soon (Ausubel, 1989). In some cases, once a partic-

Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×

ular technology path is chosen, the choice may become "locked in," regardless of the advantages of the alternatives (Arthur, 1990).

Technological trajectories are shaped by a variety of economic, social, and political forces. Such trajectories usually cannot be changed without encountering opposition from well-entrenched interests. Reconciliation of these conflicting interests requires the articulation of broad social goals by political leaders, and historically has been achieved only in times of crisis. Thus, harnessing technology in ways that are both productive and ecologically sound is a formidable undertaking, given the inertia or our political and economic structures. However, as society begins to grapple with the potentially serious environmental implications of its economic and industrial practices, the systems perspective provided by industrial ecology is likely to gain a more sympathetic heating from policymakers.

ENCOURAGING INDUSTRIAL ECOLOGY CHANGES

Practical expression of industrial ecology ideas will have to start at the design level. The product design stage offers a unique point of leverage from which to address environmental problems. Design decisions directly and indirectly determine levels of resource use, types of manufacturing processes, and the composition of waste streams. By giving designers5 the proper signals about the environmental impacts of their decisions, policymakers can address environmental concerns that arise throughout the product life cycle, from the extraction of raw materials to final disposal.

The principal conceptual questions are when and how policymakers should intervene. Companies already have a number of incentives to move toward "greener" products and processes. For instance, waste-prevention strategies can reduce materials use and energy consumption, and thereby reduce the costs of manufacturing and waste disposal, while limiting potential liability. The consideration of environmental objectives by designers can also have important implications for competitiveness. Market opportunities for environmentally sensitive goods and services are expanding rapidly. Surveys indicate that a substantial percentage of consumers are willing to pay a premium for environmentally sound products.6

But despite these incentives for the creation of "green" products and "clean" technologies, a number of technical, behavioral, economic, and informational obstacles need to be addressed. Perhaps the most important obstacles are a variety of market distortions and environmental externalities. For example, government subsidies or preferential tax treatment for the extraction of some virgin materials (e.g., timber and minerals) encourages materials inefficiency. Also, consumers do not pay the full environmental costs of products that are consumed or dissipated during use (e.g., gasoline, agricultural chemicals, and cleaners), nor do they pay the full cost of solid waste disposal. Until such distortions and environmental

Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×

costs are internalized, environmentally sound design and production decisions are likely to remain economically unattractive.

In general, policymakers can achieve internalization in two ways: by regulation or by economic instruments. Each approach has advantages and disadvantages: regulations, if properly designed, can produce swift and relatively predictable results (e.g., the mandatory phaseout of leaded gasoline), but they can also impose unnecessary costs on industry and stifle environmentally innovative designs. As an example, some environmental regulations discriminate against new technologies by prescribing rigid design standards (the so-called best available technology). Unfortunately, environmental laws have too often been written as if the world were static. Change brings new risks, but the risks to society of not innovating are usually not considered. 7

Economic instruments, such as surcharges on industrial emissions, can provide flexibility by focusing on desired outcomes rather than methods, but they can be expensive to administer and are often politically unpopular (for example, recall the opposition to the 5 cent gasoline tax, the "nickel for America"). Yet, despite such shortcomings, market-based incentives should be given serious consideration by policymakers. Many environmental problems, such as groundwater contamination or dissipation of heavy metals into the atmosphere, are not caused by large point sources of pollution and therefore cannot be easily addressed by using command-and-control methods. Due to the proliferation of design and materials technology choices, and given that product impacts are almost always multidimensional, policies need to be crafted with flexibility.8 If particularly acute environmental problems necessitate regulatory action, efforts should be made to design enforcement mechanisms so that innovative and efficient solutions are not ignored. In many cases, market mechanisms can supplement regulatory measures—for example, the excise tax on chlorofluorocarbons. Thus, the challenge for policymakers is to employ a mixture of regulations and economic instruments that encourage designers to take account of rapid technological change while simultaneously safeguarding environmental quality.9

THE IMPORTANCE OF A SYSTEMS APPROACH

From an environmental perspective, it is simplistic to view products in isolation from the production and consumption systems in which they function. The greatest environmental gains lie in changing the overall systems in which products are manufactured, used, and disposed of rather than in changing the composition of the products themselves. 10 Product design that accounts for the dynamic relationships among all companies involved in a production system has the potential to produce less waste than product design that takes account of only an individual company's waste stream. This is the central appeal of the industrial ecology concept.

But encouraging a systems approach is a nontrivial undertaking. While in

Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×

recent years industrial enterprises have demonstrated an increasing ability to manage energy and materials flows in an integrated fashion, these efforts have been highly atomistic, taking place primarily behind the factory gate. In-house waste products are indeed being recycled and reused with greater efficiency and creativity. But there has been little intra-industry and inter-industry coordination in materials management. In some cases there have been regulatory disincentives (e.g., the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act, or RCRA).11 In other cases, there has been a lack of awareness of the possibilities.

A systems solution to a design problem will often require new patterns of industrial organization, such as the formation of cooperative relationships among manufacturers, suppliers, and waste management providers. The creation of industrial networks can expand the scale of a firm's operations and thereby permit a firm to consider. design solutions that would otherwise not be possible. Such cross-company relationships could promote greater materials efficiency in the economy. However, it will not be easy for industry to consider such dramatic changes in its existing production networks. After all, long-standing relationships among manufacturers and suppliers may have to change, and millions of dollars may be invested in the existing infrastructure for production and distribution. Indeed, a systems approach requires a shift in perception by top management such that environmental quality is viewed not as a cost but as a strategic business opportunity.

Government has a key role to play here. First, there is the power of exhortation. Government can encourage new collaborative arrangements across industries and can provide research funds to facilitate such arrangements (e.g., the cooperative agreement among automakers, plastics suppliers, recyclers, and the federal government to explore methods of recovering automotive materials).12 Next, and probably most important, systems solutions can be encouraged either directly by regulation or indirectly through economic incentives. Recycled content regulations or manufacturer take-back requirements are examples of a regulatory coupling between manufacturing and waste management. The proposal of the German government to require auto manufacturers to take back and recycle their cars, for example, has stimulated the German automakers to rethink the entire industrial ecology of auto production and disposal. As a consequence, new relationships are emerging. Automakers will encourage their material suppliers to accept recovered materials from dismantlers and will specify the use of recovered materials in new car parts, thus "closing the loop." This approach though, may be more appropriate for high-value, durable products with complex material composition than for nondurable or disposable products.13

An alternative to take-back regulations involves measures to encourage corporate decision makers indirectly to take a systems approach by using economic instruments to internalize the costs of environmental services (examples include taxes on emissions or virgin materials use; tradable emissions or recycling credits; tax credits; or deposit refund schemes on packaging or hazardous products). This

Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×

approach would rely on market forces to sort out what new interfirm relationships make sense economically, while giving designers the flexibility to design products with the best combination of cost, performance, and least environmental impact. For example, a substantial carbon tax on fuels could have a dramatic impact on the systems by which products are manufactured, distributed, and disposed of, because fuels are consumed at every stage of the product life cycle.

A FOCUS ON FUNCTION

A true systems view implies a unified consideration of production and consumption activities: supply-side and demand-side requirements need to be treated in an integrated way. This implies a new way of looking at products. The opportunities for linking product design with system-oriented thinking have not been fully explored, but examples are beginning to appear in different sectors of the economy. For instance, pesticide use has declined dramatically where farmers have adopted integrated pest management schemes involving crop rotation and the use of natural predators (U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment, 1990). Due to the success of these new methods, chemical companies are no longer simply supplying pesticides to farmers but are also providing expertise on how to use those chemicals in conjunction with better field design and crop management. In effect, services (i.e., knowledge) have been substituted for chemicals.

Similarly, in the energy supply sector, many utilities are providing energy audit services, and are promoting customer use of energy-efficient equipment, instead of constructing new generating plants. Energy, after all, is used not for its own sake but rather for the services it provides, such as heating, lighting, and transportation. But to encourage decision making on a systemwide basis, utilities need to be allowed to benefit financially from investments in efficient end-use equipment. Recent changes in regulatory frameworks have played a key role in moving utilities in this direction (U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment, 1991b).

The examples of integrated pest management in the chemical sector, and demand-side management in the utility industry, can be applied in a more general way to other industries. When a product is viewed as an agency for providing a service or fulfilling a specific need, the profit incentive changes; income is generated by "optimizing the utilization of goods rather than the production of goods."14 The notion of thinking about a product in terms of the function it performs is a logical extension of total quality management philosophy. The aim of total quality management is to satisfy customer needs. Customers usually do not care how their needs are met, as long as they are indeed met. Thus, it should not matter whether a customer's requirements are satisfied by a specific product or by a service performed in lieu of that product. (For more on this subject, see Stahel, in this volume.)

Perhaps one of the more intriguing applications of this idea is the "rent mod-

Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×

el," in which manufacturers retain ownership of products and simply rent them to consumers.15 By retaining ownership of the products they lease, companies would have a strong incentive to design goods so that they can be reused or remanufactured.16 However, if the idea of renting rather than selling is to gain currency, public attitudes toward "used" goods will have to change, and government procurement regulations will have to be modified to eliminate biases against refurbished or recycled products. While government-imposed take-back laws would move industry in such a direction, policymakers should proceed cautiously. Although take-back schemes may be a good option for some products, further research on the costs and benefits for a range of products is needed. Mandated design approaches could undermine overall resource efficiency and have unforeseen environmental consequences.

THE CHALLENGE OF GOVERNANCE

A major obstacle to acceptance and application of the principles of industrial ecology is the structure of government itself.17 Congress, the writer of laws, is organized in a way that works against a systems consideration of environmental problems. Environmental policy is treated in a fragmented fashion. Air, water, and land pollution issues, along with taxes and research, are all under the jurisdiction of separate committees. One consequence of this jurisdictional division is that research needed to implement environmental regulations is often neglected.18

This fragmentation extends to the executive branch. The Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) is organized around regulatory responsibilities for protecting air, water, and land; it does not address industries or industrial sectors in a natural way, and its technical expertise in design and manufacturing is slight. The Department of Commerce, on the other hand, is concerned with the competitiveness of industrial sectors, but has little environmental expertise. There is considerable technical expertise in the U.S. Department of Energy's (DOE's) national labs that could be brought to bear on improving design for energy efficiency and solid waste recycling processes, but environmental quality has not traditionally been a part of DOE's mission.

Recognizing opportunities for systems-oriented design requires that the economic performance and environmental impact of industries or sectors be viewed in an integrated way. Individual companies have little incentive to promote an overall greener vision of their sector. And in general, this cannot be done in the context of a single federal agency. A greener transportation sector, for example, may involve not only improved vehicle fuel efficiency but better management of materials used in automotive, rail, and aviation applications, as well as changes in urban design. An institutional focus above the agency level might spur a more holistic analysis of total sectoral issues, through forums or grant programs.

In Japan the Ministry of International Trade and Industry (MITI), which has responsibility for both trade and competitiveness matters, is also involved in im-

Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×

plementing a new recycling law. MITI's involvement is expected to be a strong inducement for companies to comply in a timely way. But in United States, there is no comparable institution that can address trade, competitiveness, and the environment in a coherent fashion. In general, there has been little or no coupling between U.S. technology policy and national environmental requirements.

While it would not make sense to create a separate institution within government to promote industrial ecology concepts, greater coordination between agencies would certainly be desirable. Industrial ecology concepts could be integrated into new interagency initiatives, such as the Manufacturing Technology Initiative and the Advanced Materials and Processing Program announced by the White House in early 1992. In addition, consideration could be given to creating a national environmental technology laboratory (Allenby, unpublished draft). 19

THE NEED FOR INFORMATION

Government institutions cannot rationally formulate policies without knowing which environmental problems pose the greatest risks. Policymakers currently lack critical information on how materials flow through the economy and about the relative dangers of different materials, products, and waste streams. For instance, there has been considerable concern expressed about the releases of mercury from the incineration of discarded batteries. Yet these releases may be small compared with mercury releases from coal combustion in power plants. Thus, in identifying the major sources of environmental pollutants, it is clear that a systems view is of paramount importance. We need to focus our resources—whether financial or technical—where the risks are greatest, not where the problems are most visible.

CONCLUSION

Since our industrial activities have multiple environmental effects that are not easily disentangled, a systemic approach to environmental policy is needed. But given the barriers enumerated here, such a change in perspective will not come about easily. It is to be hoped that as we increase our understanding of the interconnections between economic and ecological systems, there will be greater political will to develop coherent environmental strategies.

NOTES

1.  

The world economy is consuming resources and generating wastes at unprecedented rates. In the past 100 years, the world's industrial production increased more than fiftyfold. See Rostow, 1978, pp. 48-49.

2.  

Industrial ecology refers to the set of relationships among firms in industrial production networks, and the effects of these relationships on the flow of energy and materials through the economy and on the natural world in which the economy is embedded. Some observers envision

Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×

   

systems of industrial production that would emulate the web of interconnections found in the natural world. Nature manages its use of materials in a highly efficient manner. Ideally, production relationships would be organized so that wastes from one process could be used as inputs into other industrial processes.

3.  

International trade has grown at nearly twice the rate of the gross domestic product over the past decade. About 50 percent of the manufactured imports of the largest industrial countries consist of intermediate, not finished, goods—a reflection of the global nature of production. See OECD (1992).

4.  

As an example, more than 300 million metric tons of carbon are embodied in the imported manufactured products of six of the largest industrial nations. (Carbon content includes both direct and indirect carbon associated with industrial production.) The sum of carbon embodied in imports for these six countries is about 20 percent of the amount of carbon produced yearly by the United States, surpasses the quantity generated by Japan, and is roughly twice the amount of carbon produced by France. See Wyckoff and Roop (1992).

5.  

As used here, the term designers refers to all decision makers who participate in the early stages of product development. This includes a wide variety of disciplines: industrial designers, engineering designers, manufacturing engineers, and graphic and packaging designers, as well as managers and marketing professionals.

6.  

See, for example, The Roper Organization, Inc., "The Environment: Public Attitudes and Individual Behavior," a study conducted for S.C. Johnson and Son, Inc., July 1990.

7.  

The accumulation of knowledge or technological capital can be just as important to future generations as environmental capital. A central ethical question, however, is whether the current generation can fulfill its obligations to future generations by simply substituting technological capital for rapidly disappearing natural capital.

8.  

There are typically many environmental trade-offs associated with the use of a specific material. For instance, the new classes of high-temperature superconductors, which potentially offer vast improvements in power transmission efficiency and have other promising new applications, are quite toxic; the best of them is based on thallium, a highly toxic heavy metal. The fact that products that use toxic materials can perform socially useful functions, or even have comparative environmental benefits, underscores the need for a flexible approach to environmental questions.

9.  

For greater detail on the available policy options, see U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment (1992).

10.  

For example, 80 percent of the waste from a typical fast food chain is produced behind the counter, before food and drinks reach the customer. About 35 percent of the waste generated is corrugated boxes, and another 35 percent is food scrap. Thus, changing delivery methods, and pursuing composting, would have a much greater impact than simply "lightweighting" the packaging of hamburgers. Resources would probably be better spent examining the dynamics of the food chain's distribution and production systems, rather than performing a series of costly life cycle assessments on each of the products used in those systems. Depending on the context, such a systems focus could conceivably result in the elimination of certain products (the ultimate in source reduction), or in the creation of feedback loops that would facilitate recycling and reuse.

11.  

In the view of some, the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act (RCRA) has impeded the recycling efforts of industry. When a material falls out of a given manufacturing process, it becomes by legal definition a "waste," and is often subject to stiff regulation. The effect of this regulation is to limit any further industrial uses of the material, and, by default, the material really does become a waste.

12.  

It may be necessary to modify antitrust laws to encourage the formation of research consortia and other collaborative links between industries.

13.  

Companies such as Xerox and IBM have implemented take-back programs for several years. Because of the high-value, knowledge-intensive nature of their products, these companies have considerable incentive to recover and reuse product subsystems and components. However,

Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×

   

little analysis has been done to determine whether the recovery of low-value items such as food packaging makes environmental or economic sense.

14.  

Walter Stahel, The Product-Life Institute, Geneva, Switzerland. For more on this idea, see Giarini and Stahel (1989).

15.  

See note 14 above.

16.  

Remanufacturing involves the restoration of old products by refurbishing usable parts and introducing new components where necessary. It simultaneously results in product life extension and promotes reuse of subcomponents and materials. Apart from the economic benefits that can accrue to a manufacturer, the reuse of high value-added components takes advantage of the original manufacturing investment in energy and materials. This yields greater environmental benefits than simply recycling the constituent materials of the components.

17.  

The vitality, adaptability, and resiliency of biological organisms derive not from the mere multiplication of cells but from the efficacy of their organization. This lesson should not be forgotten as we assess the effectiveness of our political "metabolism."

18.  

For example, volatile organic compounds (VOCs), have been regulated for 20 years, but there has been little actual monitoring of VOC emissions. Emissions are not actually measured but are estimated using models. But the accuracy of these models is in question since the effect of emissions from vegetation is poorly understood. Thus, it is difficult to assess the efficacy of the VOC regulations. See U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment (1989).

19.  

Several bills have been introduced in the Congress to create such an agency.

REFERENCES

Allenby, Braden. Unpublished draft. Why We Need a National Environmental Technology Laboratory (And How to Make One).

Arthur, W. Brian. 1990. Positive feedbacks in the economy. Scientific American 262(2):92-99.

Ausubel, Jesse. 1989. Regularities in technological development: An environmental view, Pp. 70-91 in Technology and Environment, Jesse Ausubel and Hedy Sladovich, eds., Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press.

Ayres, Robert U. 1992. Toxic heavy metals: Materials cycle optimization. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 89(3):815-820.


Frosch, Robert A. 1992. Industrial ecology: A philosophical introduction. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 89(3):800-803.


Galloway, James N., J. David Thornton, Stephen A. Norton, Herbert L. Volchok, and Ronald A. N. McLean. 1982. Atmospheric Environment 16(7):1678.

Giarini, Orio, and W. Stahel. 1989. The Limits to Certainty: Facing Risks in the New Service Economy. Boston, Mass.: Kluwer Academic Publishers.


Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 1992. The International Sourcing of Intermediate Inputs. DSTI/STII/IND(92)1, Paris (January).


Ponting, Clive. 1990. Historical perspective on sustainable development. Environment 32(9).


Rostow, W. W. 1978. The World Economy: History and Prospects. Austin, Texas: University of Texas Press.


U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment. 1989. Catching Our Breath: Next Steps for Reducing Urban Ozone. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.

U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment. 1990. Beneath the Bottom Line:

Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×

Agricultural Approaches to Reduce Agrichemical Contamination of Groundwater. OTA-F-418. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.

U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment. 1991a. Changing by Degrees: Steps to Reduce Greenhouse Gases. OTA-0-482. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.

U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment. 1991b. Energy Technology Choices: Shaping Our Future. OTA-E-493. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.

U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment. 1992. Green Products by Design: Choices for a Cleaner Environment. OTA-E-541. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.

Wyckoff, Andrew W., and J. M. Roop. 1992. The Embodiment of Carbon in Imports of Manufactured Products: Implications for International Agreements on Greenhouse Gas Emissions. OECD, Paris (May).

Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×
This page in the original is blank.
Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×
Page 123
Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×
Page 124
Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×
Page 125
Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×
Page 126
Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×
Page 127
Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×
Page 128
Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×
Page 129
Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×
Page 130
Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×
Page 131
Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×
Page 132
Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×
Page 133
Suggested Citation:"Industrial Ecology: The Role of Government." National Academy of Engineering. 1994. The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/2129.
×
Page 134
Next: Emerging Industrial Environmental Practice »
The Greening of Industrial Ecosystems Get This Book
×
Buy Paperback | $75.00
MyNAP members save 10% online.
Login or Register to save!
Download Free PDF

In the 1970s, the first wave of environmental regulation targeted specific sources of pollutants. In the 1990s, concern is focused not on the ends of pipes or the tops of smokestacks but on sweeping regional and global issues.

This landmark volume explores the new industrial ecology, an emerging framework for making environmental factors an integral part of economic and business decision making. Experts on this new frontier explore concepts and applications, including:

  • Bringing international law up to par with many national laws to encourage industrial ecology principles.
  • Integrating environmental costs into accounting systems.
  • Understanding design for environment, industrial "metabolism," and sustainable development and how these concepts will affect the behavior of industrial and service firms.

The volume looks at negative and positive aspects of technology and addresses treatment of waste as a raw material.

This volume will be important to domestic and international policymakers, leaders in business and industry, environmental specialists, and engineers and designers.

  1. ×

    Welcome to OpenBook!

    You're looking at OpenBook, NAP.edu's online reading room since 1999. Based on feedback from you, our users, we've made some improvements that make it easier than ever to read thousands of publications on our website.

    Do you want to take a quick tour of the OpenBook's features?

    No Thanks Take a Tour »
  2. ×

    Show this book's table of contents, where you can jump to any chapter by name.

    « Back Next »
  3. ×

    ...or use these buttons to go back to the previous chapter or skip to the next one.

    « Back Next »
  4. ×

    Jump up to the previous page or down to the next one. Also, you can type in a page number and press Enter to go directly to that page in the book.

    « Back Next »
  5. ×

    Switch between the Original Pages, where you can read the report as it appeared in print, and Text Pages for the web version, where you can highlight and search the text.

    « Back Next »
  6. ×

    To search the entire text of this book, type in your search term here and press Enter.

    « Back Next »
  7. ×

    Share a link to this book page on your preferred social network or via email.

    « Back Next »
  8. ×

    View our suggested citation for this chapter.

    « Back Next »
  9. ×

    Ready to take your reading offline? Click here to buy this book in print or download it as a free PDF, if available.

    « Back Next »
Stay Connected!