National Academies Press: OpenBook

Measuring Poverty: A New Approach (1995)

Chapter: The Rothbarth and Other Methods

« Previous: The Engel and Iso-Prop Methods
Suggested Citation:"The Rothbarth and Other Methods." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 172
Suggested Citation:"The Rothbarth and Other Methods." National Research Council. 1995. Measuring Poverty: A New Approach. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. doi: 10.17226/4759.
×
Page 173

Below is the uncorrected machine-read text of this chapter, intended to provide our own search engines and external engines with highly rich, chapter-representative searchable text of each book. Because it is UNCORRECTED material, please consider the following text as a useful but insufficient proxy for the authoritative book pages.

ADJUSTING POVERTY THRESHOLDS 172 be used to compare any family type with any other family type and so to produce a complete set of equivalence scale values. This method will presumably also capture any economies of scale so long as they are reflected in the food share, as they must be if the Engel assertion is correct. It is also possible to extend the Engel method beyond the share of food to the share of other necessities; this iso-prop approach was introduced by Watts (1967; see also Seneca and Taussig, 1971) and underlies the Canadian low- income cut-offs (LICOs) (see Wolfson and Evans, 1989). When goods other than food are included, the assumption is that the share of those goods indicates family welfare. Hence, the procedure will work in the same way as does Engel's, provided that the share falls with income (because the goods are necessities) and rises with family size. The Engel method and its iso-prop variants are only as good as the basic assumption that the food (or other necessity) share correctly indicates family welfare, which can be argued. Even if Engel's Law is correct, and even if larger families spend a larger share of their budget on food, there is no automatic implication that the food share is a valid indicator of the standard of living. Engel's Law says that richer families have lower food shares, so that, among families of the same composition, it makes sense to argue that families with higher food shares are poorer than families with lower food shares, which is no more than a restatement of the law. Larger families spend a larger share on food, as do poorer families, but it does not follow that larger families spend more on food because they are poorer or that one can measure how much poorer they are by calculating the income drop that would have produced the same effect. Nicholson (1976) has convincingly argued that the food share is a poor indicator of the standard of living. Consider again a married couple who have their first child, and suppose for the purposes of the argument that one has managed to calculate the correct compensation and that the appropriate amount has been paid to the family. What will happen? The parents have been fully compensated and so are expected to spend, out of their share of family resources, the same fraction on food as they did before the birth of the child. But a child consumes mostly food and clothing, so this fully compensated family actually spends a larger share of its total budget on food. According to Engel, the family is worse off than it was before because its food share is higher, and it must be paid more to compensate it for the cost of the child. By this argument, the compensation calculated according to the Engel method assigns too large a cost to children. Nicholson's argument is a persuasive one, and we do not believe that the food (or necessities) share should be used to calculate equivalence scale values. The Rothbarth and Other Methods Instead of using food share, Rothbarth (1943) used expenditures on adult goods as an indicator of the standard of

ADJUSTING POVERTY THRESHOLDS 173 living, if not of the whole family, at least of its adult members. Using the same example of a married couple with a child, the argument is that the child brings needs but no resources and that those needs can be met only by making cuts elsewhere in the budget. If one can find some goods that children do not consume —alcohol, tobacco, and adult clothing being the most obvious and frequently used examples—their consumption should decline when a child is added to the family. The decline is caused by the diversion of income to the child, so that if one can calculate the reduction in income that would produce that same decline, one has calculated the amount of income diverted to the child, and, thus, its cost. The mechanics of the procedure are similar to those of the Engel method and are illustrated in Figure 3-3. Again, there is curve A for the original family and curve B for the larger family containing the child, but now they slope upwards, since expenditure on adult goods is assumed to rise with income. And it is the lower curve, curve B, that is associated with the larger family because expenditures on adult goods are cut to make room for the additional expenses associated with the child. The original family with income y0 spends a0 on adult goods, which is reduced to a1 in the presence of the child. If income is increased to y1 from y0, the original level of expenditure on adult goods is restored, and, according to Rothbarth, so are the living standards of the parents. The difference y1 – y0 is therefore the cost of the child, and the ratio of y1 to y0 is the equivalence scale value for the two family types. FIGURE 3-3 Rothbarth method for equivalence scales. (See text for discussion.)

Next: Subjective Scales »
Measuring Poverty: A New Approach Get This Book
×
Buy Paperback | $75.00 Buy Ebook | $59.99
MyNAP members save 10% online.
Login or Register to save!
Download Free PDF

Each year's poverty figures are anxiously awaited by policymakers, analysts, and the media. Yet questions are increasing about the 30-year-old measure as social and economic conditions change.

In Measuring Poverty a distinguished panel provides policymakers with an up-to-date evaluation of:

  • Concepts and procedures for deriving the poverty threshold, including adjustments for different family circumstances.
  • Definitions of family resources.
  • Procedures for annual updates of poverty measures.

The volume explores specific issues underlying the poverty measure, analyzes the likely effects of any changes on poverty rates, and discusses the impact on eligibility for public benefits. In supporting its recommendations the panel provides insightful recognition of the political and social dimensions of this key economic indicator.

Measuring Poverty will be important to government officials, policy analysts, statisticians, economists, researchers, and others involved in virtually all poverty and social welfare issues.

  1. ×

    Welcome to OpenBook!

    You're looking at OpenBook, NAP.edu's online reading room since 1999. Based on feedback from you, our users, we've made some improvements that make it easier than ever to read thousands of publications on our website.

    Do you want to take a quick tour of the OpenBook's features?

    No Thanks Take a Tour »
  2. ×

    Show this book's table of contents, where you can jump to any chapter by name.

    « Back Next »
  3. ×

    ...or use these buttons to go back to the previous chapter or skip to the next one.

    « Back Next »
  4. ×

    Jump up to the previous page or down to the next one. Also, you can type in a page number and press Enter to go directly to that page in the book.

    « Back Next »
  5. ×

    To search the entire text of this book, type in your search term here and press Enter.

    « Back Next »
  6. ×

    Share a link to this book page on your preferred social network or via email.

    « Back Next »
  7. ×

    View our suggested citation for this chapter.

    « Back Next »
  8. ×

    Ready to take your reading offline? Click here to buy this book in print or download it as a free PDF, if available.

    « Back Next »
Stay Connected!